Sign the Resolution for a Federal Commission on Drug Policy
Contents | Feedback | Search | DRCNet Home Page | Join DRCNet
DRCNet Library | Schaffer Library | Heroin and the opiates
INTERIM DRAFT FINAL REPORT:
HISTORICAL REVIEW OF OPIUM/HEROIN PRODUCTION
by Alfred W. McCoy
CONTENTS:
I. Executive Summary:
II. Analysis of Epochs, Trends & Causality:
1.) Glossary of Basic Concepts.
2.) Opium as Folk Pharmacopoeia (Up to 1600).
3.) Early European Opium Trade (1640-1773).
4.) Era of European Mercantilism (1773-1858).
5.) High Imperial Opium Trade (1858-1907).
6.) Multilateral Control & Syndicate Crime
(1907-1940).
7.) War & Transition (1940-1947).
8.) Cold War Opium Expansion (1948-1972).
9.) Origins of US Bilateral Suppression
(1973-1979).
10.) Production Increase in Asian Zone
(1979-1989).
11.) Global Proliferation of Opium (1989-1994).
III. Policy Implications & Recommendations:
IV. Notes on Text & Tables:
V. Graphs, Tables:
I. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY:
1.) Summary of Trends by Opium Epoch:
a.) Opium as Folk Pharmacopoeia (Up to 1600):
1.) Dominant Trend: Over the space of some three millennia, opium spread from its home in the eastern Mediterranean to China, creating an extended Asian opium zone. For the first time in recorded history, opium became a recreational drug in the cities of Mughal India.
2.) Implication: The persistent role of opiates as folk medicine and recreational euphoric for nearly 4,000 years raises questions about the chances of effecting its eradication in the near future.
b.) Early European Opium Trade (1640-1773):
1.) Dominant Trend: In this period, there was a shift from a limited trade in opium though intra-Asian networks to an expanding European commerce that stimulated both supply and demand. Working separately, European mercantile companies commercialized both opium cultivation and commerce, making it the basis of a profitable long distance trade in low-weight, high-value goods.
2.) Implication: During this era, opium's extraordinarily profitability, combining the constant demand of a staple with the high price of a luxury, becomes manifest. As an addictive drug, opium requires a daily dose giving it the inelastic demand of a basic foodstuff. Long distance sea-trade in bulk foods was still beyond the capacity of the era's maritime technology, but opium had the low weight and high mark-up of luxury goods like cloves or pepper. Compounding its profitability, the Chinese emperor prohibited opium in 1729, thus denying China the opportunity to produce opium and inadvertently conceding British merchants a de facto monopoly over the trade.
c.) European Mercantilism (1773-1858):
1.) Dominant Trend: Under the doctrine of mercantilism, all successful European colonial ventures in Asia involved commercialization of drugs in some form--caffeine, nicotine, or opiates. This 18th century trade transformed these drugs from luxury goods into commodities of mass consumption, making them integral to the economies and lifestyles of both Asian and Atlantic nations. Within the monopolistic logic of mercantilism, the British East India Company achieved the highest profits from its export of Indian opium to China because, from 1773 to 1830, its strong controls over key aspects--production, export, and sales.
2.) Implication: From the late 18th century onward, opium became a major trade commodity. Under the British East India Company (BEIC), centralized controls accelerated the export of Indian opium to China--from 13 tons in 1729 to and 2,558 tons in 1839.
d.) High Imperial Opium Trade (1858-1907):
1.) Dominant Trend: During the latter half of the 19th century, opium became a major global commodity. Across the Asian opium zone, from the Balkans to Manchuria, there was a steady increase of local opium cultivation and consumption. Moreover, in the latter half of the 19th century, the modern pharmaceutical industry made opiates a drug of mass abuse in the cities of the West--Europe, the Americas, and Australia.
2.) Implication: By the early 20th century, opium and its derivatives, morphine and heroin, had become a major global commodity equivalent in scale to other drugs such as coffee and tea.
e.) Multilateral Control (1907-1940):
1.) Dominant Trend: Within the Protestant churches of England and America a moral
reaction to the excesses of a market-driven expansion of drug abuse inspired a global
anti-opium movement in the late 19th Century. For the first time in the modern era, the
anti-opium movement, in alliance with the larger temperance crusade, succeeded in winning
new laws from the state restricting the individual's control over the body. With the
passage of the Harrison Narcotics Act in 1914, the American state, for the first time,
imposed the force of law over the right to use or abuse the body as the individual saw
fit. Through a complex diplomacy from 1909 to 1925, the League of Nations adopted
restrictions on the recreational use of heroin and opium that produced a major drop in
legal production.
2.) Implication: The prewar attempt at multilateral controls over narcotics had a mixed
result. Although repression did reduce both production and consumption, the high profits
inherent in the opiates traffic remained to sustain criminal syndicates which now acted as
an unintended market response to limit state control over the drug trade.
Despite all these considerable drawbacks, multilateral controls do have their successes.
Through these efforts, the constant, century-long upward trajectory in drug abuse was
finally broken, and, for the first time since the 18th century, both use and production
began to decline. World opium production dropped from 41,600 tons in 1907 to 16,600 tons
in 1934, while licit world heroin production fell sharply from an 20,000 lbs. in 1926 to
only 2,200 lbs. in 1931.
f.) War & Transition (1940-1947):
1.) Dominant Trend: During World War II, restrictions on shipping and strict port security produced a marked hiatus in global opium trafficking. Denied illicit opiates from Asia, the United States drew limited supplies of low-grade heroin from Mexico that failed to meet even a fraction of consumer demand. By the end of the war, the US addict population had dropped to an historic low of some twenty thousand. Once smuggling resumed after the war, however, the US addict population resumed the habit.
2.) Implication: Under extreme circumstances, a reduction in drug supply can lead to a
sudden, albeit ephemeral, decrease in consumption.
g.) Cold War Opium Expansion (1948-1972):
1.) Dominant Trend: The Cold War brought major changes to the world's illicit opium
traffic. The Communist victory in China eliminated the world's major opium market within a
decade, removing the globe's major producer and consumer of opiates from the market.
Although the Asian opium zone contracted geographically, Cold War geo-politics, combined
with illicit market forces, stimulated a steady increase in opium production in the
remaining area, which now stretched from Turkey to Thailand.
Supplied by the Asian zone, other markets--particularly in the United States and
Iran--expanded their consumption of opiates steadily during this period.
2.) Implication: External intervention in the remote tribal areas along the Asian opium zone contributed to the rise of drug lords and their armies, allowing them to position themselves for a massive expansion of local opium production. By providing arms, logistics, organization, and political protection, external alliances created the preconditions for a later leap in opium production in Burma and Afghanistan.
h.) US Bilateral Suppression (1973-1979):
1.) Dominant Trend: Although repression disrupted the global heroin trade for several
years, over the longer term Nixon's drug war stimulated both opium production and heroin
consumption. Ignoring these lessons, the Reagan and Bush administrations later pursued
parallel policies in Latin America with dismal results. In essence, all three drug wars
extended a local law enforcement model into the international arena in a way that failed
to reduce either drug production or exports. Stimulated in part by three US drug wars,
Asian opium production increased from 1,000 tons in 1970 to 4,000 tons in 1989.
2.) Implication: When law enforcement is applied to such an elaborate commerce, drug syndicates usually react in ways not foreseen by enforcement agencies. Treating this global commodity trade as if it were a localized vice, U.S. drug agencies often apply repression without any awareness of the intricate dynamics of these worldwide marketing systems. For both legal and illicit commodities, a crop failure in one production zone--whether from war, drought, or disease--creates a shortage of supply and raises the price for producers elsewhere, stimulating increased production in the next crop cycle.
i.) Increase in Asian Zone (1979-1989):
1.) Dominant Trend: For the first time in opium's history, highland drug lords began to act as independent entrepreneurs, responding creatively to market opportunities for their product. In Burma, for example, opium production increased exponentially from 550 tons in 1981 to 2,500 in 1989, in large part through the efforts of leading warlords like Khun Sa. Similarly, the emergence of Gulbuddin Hekmatyar as the dominant rebel leader in Afghanistan created a parallel figure of power who could control much of the country's opium production, heroin processing, and export.
2.) Implication: The capacity of powerful opium warlords in Burma and Afghanistan to both produce and export has had a growing influence on Western heroin markets--sending vast new supplies of Burmese heroin to America and giving the Sicilian mafia a major new role as brokers for South West Asian heroin to Europe and the United States.
j.) Global Proliferation of Opium (1989-1994):
1.) Dominant Trend: In the early 1990s, heroin recovered its historic preeminence as a leading illicit narcotic and became something of a "world" drug. Expansion of established opium areas in Burma and Afghanistan, combined with introduction of the crop into Central Asia and Latin America, led to a steady increase in world supply. Increased opium harvests have led to a dramatic proliferation of heroin abuse around the globe--a phenomenon so vast that we can speak, without hyperbole, of a "globalization" of heroin consumption. Paralleling the rise of use in established consuming regions, heroin abuse shot upward in new areas of Europe and Asia.
2.) Implication: World opium supply is growing without any apparent restraint. Since all opium produced is always consumed, rising supply is now a powerful force driving a sharp increase in world heroin consumption, creating insatiable demand for the drug, not seen since early 19th Century China, that may, in turn, yield further production increases in Latin America or Central Asia.
2.) Changing Patterns in Opium Production:
a.) Bilateral Suppression: As demonstrated in Turkey in the 1970s and the Andes in the 1980s, bilateral suppression efforts can effect dramatic short-term reductions in supply that will, in the next crop year, lead to an increase in total global production of narcotics. Similarly, heroin supplies, when denied entry into one market, seek another, resulting in a proliferation of consumption and an overall increase in world demand for opiates. Should such bilateral operations, by some miracle, succeed in effecting a long-term reduction in supply, domestic dealers could turn to the manufacture of synthetics. In the US during the 1970s, for example, criminal syndicates reacted to a shortage of natural drugs by expanding domestic manufacture of synthetics, producing a "speed" or amphetamine epidemic.
b.) China's Perfect Coercion: In the century past, the most important development in the global traffic was China's effective suppression of opium production and use after 1949. Judging by the success of these efforts, perfect repression under an efficient authoritarian regime can effect a dramatic reduction in both consumption and production of drugs. However, China's experience is historically unique and is not relevant as a model for the more open political systems that have begun emerging since 1989.
c.) State Power: Even when drugs are produced in remote terrain and consumed in secret,
the state plays a major role in their political economy. In circumstances where opium
production or consumption are legal, an efficient state can effect a rapid change in drug
supply and use. From 1906 to 1934, multilateral efforts by the League of Nations, working
through its member states, succeeded in reducing global opium production from 41,600 tons
to 16,600 largely because the states involved were regulating a legal production and
consumption that was, in effect, under their control.
Approaching the question of the state from another perspective, the lessons of the past
century indicate that opium production cannot continue over the long term in a strong
state committed to its eradication. Conversely, protracted, high-level opium production
requires either the attenuation of state power in the producing regions, as in Burma and
Afghanistan in the 1980s, or extensive official corruption, as Thailand in the 1960s, Laos
in the 1970s, or Burma in the 1990s. Thus, any cluster of policies that increases state
control over opium producing regions and simultaneously restrains official corruption over
drugs will contribute to a long-term reduction in both cultivation and trafficking.
d.) Response to Repression: Market response to all government control and eradication
efforts is complex and unpredictable. Since the 1920s, syndicate response to all
suppression efforts has been quick, supple, sophisticated, and often capable of
compromising even the best attempts.
Similarly, even the most effective multilateral opium suppression efforts have complex
consequences. For example, the UN Drug Control Program in Thailand succeeded in reducing
the opium cultivation, thereby raising the price of smoking opium to local addicts,
producing an epidemic of HIV infection through needle sharing.
e.) Consequences of Long-Term Change: Projecting the patterns of historical changes
forward over the next half-century leads to some contradictory and inconclusive trends:
(a.) as has already occurred in the Thai highlands, population pressures may tend to bring
government services into the opium-growing zones, producing improved para-military access
and increased state controls; and, b.) over the medium term, population pressures that
reduce available arable land could drive highland population towards increased opium
cultivation.
With remarkable speed and facility, multi-national corporations and telecommunications are
pulling us towards a global community that might promote a subtle sense of shared
humanity, reducing the will of societies to inflict addiction upon another.
Simultaneously, however, there is an equally powerful countervailing trend toward the
assertion of primordial identities that may well have the opposite effect. For forty
years, the Cold War imposed an artificial bipolar division over the globe that led rival
superpowers to the defend the territorial integrity of their respective clients. With the
end of the Cold War, there has then been a recrudescence of religion, regionalism, race,
and ethnicity that may well lead to the fragmentation of the invented nations that were
carved out of the colonial world at the end of World War II.
The rise of new micro-states from the margins of established nations has several possible
implications for future opium production: (a.) during a period of insurgency against an
established state, rebel groups, like Khun Sa's Mong Tai Army, will become more dependent
upon opium finance and resist drug repression; (b.) faced with the threat of regional
secessionist movements, nations will become less able to impose unpopular opium-control
programs upon volatile minority areas; and, (c.) once an ethnic group actually secedes,
the new state will, in all probability, become more cooperative with UN and US drug
control programs to win international aid and consolidate the new state's controls over
its periphery.
3.) Policy Implications of Historic Patterns:
a.) Multilateral Policy: During the 20th Century, multilateral efforts have been more effective than bilateral initiatives in effecting narcotics suppression. From 1906 to 1934, multilateral efforts by the League of Nations reduced global opium production from 41,624 tons to an estimated 16,653. By contrast, between 1970 and 1990, an era of the intense US bilateral "drug wars," world illicit opium production increased from 1,154 tons to 4,209. Since bilateral operations are, by their very nature, focused on a single producing country, market dynamics will mean that, over the long term, a successful eradication will stimulate illicit price and production elsewhere, leading to a net global increase in opium supply.
b.) Supply Reduction: Any attempt at solving America's heroin problem by reducing
global opium production is unrealistic. For the past two decades, three US presidents have
waged a "war on drugs" with the aim of ameliorating America's narcotics problem
by reducing global supply. Examined closely, this strategy seems unlikely to reduce global
opium supply for several reasons: (a.) successful bilateral eradication has, over the past
quarter century, stimulated both drug production and consumption; (b.) the elimination of
US heroin supply would require that opium cultivation virtually disappear from the face of
the globe; and, (c.) world supply will, in all probability, increase sharply in coming
decades.
Despite short-term success, Nixon's eradication of illicit opium cultivation in Turkey
during the 1970s stimulated opium production elsewhere in the Asian zone, just as his
interception of US-bound heroin shipments from Thailand stimulated narcotics consumption
in Europe. Viewed historically, each short-term success in bilateral interdiction
stimulates global opiates production and consumption, compounding the problem over the
long term.
Since America consumes a tiny share of world supply and pays the highest price, illicit
market dynamics make a supply-side solution to the US heroin problem unlikely. In 1985,
for example, the US consumed only 6 tons of opium out of a world production of 1,465
tons--just 0.4 percent of the total. Since the US pays the highest price and thus offers
dealers at all levels the widest profit margin, it will consume the world's
"last" 6 tons of opium. In effect, the drug war strategy requires that the US
eradicate 99.6 percent of the world's opium before it gets to that last, critical 0.4
percent destined for the its market.
Complicating the issue further, illicit opium farming is spreading rapidly to new areas in
Central Asia and Latin America, raising total world supply. It is very possible that world
opium supply will double in the next five years and then double again within the decade.
Given declining US resources and rising world opium production, a supply-side solution to
America's heroin problem seems an impossibility.
c.) Demand Reduction: Looking back on the past 300 years of human history, there are only a very few societies that have succeeded in reducing their level of gross opiates consumption:
1.) Between World War I and World War II, the United States managed to reduce its
overall level of opiates consumption through a series of demand-side measures. By banning
legal narcotics sales between 1914 and 1923, the US gained the instruments to suppress
legal use, effecting a gradual gross reduction in use. Simultaneously, a mass campaign of
education and moral injunction educated the American people to avoid opiates addiction, a
phenomenon that was only gradually being analyzed and understood.
2.) During the decade following its revolution, the People's Republic of China used a mix
of coercion, compulsory treatment, and mass education to eliminate the world's largest
opiate addict population.
3.) During the late 1970s, the transitory effect of successful drug suppression in Turkey
and Thailand combined with a drop in demand as Vietnam-era addicts weaned themselves from
the drug combined to produce a sudden drop in the estimated number of American addicts
from 500,000 to 200,000. Since the demand change was specific to the experience of a
single generation and the supply reduction was ephemeral, the fundamental demand for
heroin remained and abuse levels rose again in the 1980s as supplies increased.
From these experiences, we can determine some of the following attributes of successful attempts at demand reduction: (a.) all have been multi-faceted with a mix of coercion, voluntarism, education, and supply reduction; (b.) in both China and the US successful demand reduction efforts have occurred at times when narcotics supply, or availability, has also been reduced; (c.) both states have used coercion to punish dealers and recidivist consumers; and, (d.) coercion has been successfully complemented by mass movements that combine social disapproval and education to inspire individuals to end their abuse voluntarily.
d.) Policy Paradigms: Over the past half-century, US drug policy has been framed, in succession, around two inappropriate paradigms of coercion. During the 1950s, the FBN used the classic 19th century police paradigm which applied localized coercion to the eradication of domestic vice trading. Since the 1970s, the executive has used a martial metaphor of war, applying the military logic of short, intense campaigns with fixed spatial or strategic objectives to an elusive global commodity. Recognizing the power of paradigms to shape concepts and thereby frame policy, it might be best to adopt a more appropriate health or disease paradigm for US drug policy. At the level of domestic drug abuse, our policy should be removed from the criminal justice system and returned to the realm of public health where it could be handled like a disease such as tuberculosis or influenza. Like a virulent disease, a global commodity such as opium can be best eradicated only through a cooperative world-wide effort.
e.) Customs Barrier: Although strict controls at the national frontier are limited in their effectiveness, they do nonetheless serve as an informal customs barrier that can at least restrain the entry of drugs. Just as high protective tariffs discourage but do not eliminate legal imports, so an efficient customs operation can serve as informal market factor that discourages, within limits, unrestricted narcotics imports. Similarly, dropping the custom shield might serve as informal invitation to illicit drug imports. As noted above, no society has ever been able to implement demand reduction when opiates are in ample supply. Conversely, all opiates imported into a consuming society have eventually, in some way, been consumed, leading to the inference that the level of supply sets the level of demand.
f.) Need for Caution in Framing Any Policy: In any discussion of solutions to the problem of global opium supply, we must begin with an essential humility. Any drug that finds such resonance within the chemistry of the human brain, any commodity that is so interwoven into the fabric of modern capitalism, cannot be easily eliminated, even with the most judicious policy.
4.) Scenarios for Future Policy Options:
a.) Continued Repression: If the United States continues its current policy of repression--with international bilateral operations, Customs controls, and domestic policing--then the probable outcome will be over the long term might be as follows.
1.) Projecting current patterns forward, heroin use will continue grow both
domestically and globally, the crime rate will climb, and the US prison population will
increase without cease.
2.) Assuming that the US continues current attempts at eradication, bilateral repression,
where attempted, will continue to stimulate opium cultivation, contributing to a rapidly
increasing global supply of drugs.
3.) Even if the US withdraws from international suppression operations, over the medium
term there is every indication that world opium supply will continue its current rate of
rapid increase.
4.) US Customs will fail to slow the import of drugs into the US, allowing the increased
world opium supply to enter America and stimulate a rising level of heroin consumption.
b.) Legalization: If the United States were to abandon all attempts at drug suppression and legalize narcotics, the reaction in the market would likely be far more complex than advocates of this radical policy alternative have suggested.
1.) Assuming that drug use is legalized only for adults and not for minors, then
legalization, with unrestricted legal sales to adults, might increase US consumption of
narcotics.
2.)If we adopt a strict clinical control system to distribute legalized heroin and cocaine
to adults, then, as happened in the United Kingdom in recent decades, a parallel illegal
traffic might spring up beside the legal clinics, servicing those who wish to control
their own consumption.
3.) If we adopt a laissez-faire system of legal narcotic sales, then impoverished adult
users may avail of the opportunity to earn survival income by diverting supplies to
underage users.
c.) Policy of "Regulation:" Instead of the drug war with its doomed attempt at a total eradication of drug use, there are several policy alternatives the US could adopt to improve the narcotics situation. If America's drug problem cannot be solved, then at least it can be managed rationally.
1.) By forcing the DEA to abandon its unreflective buy-and-bust approach, the US
government can restrain the DEA from inadvertently stimulating global opium production
with its bilateral interdiction.
2.) After abandoning the DEA's bilateral enforcement effort, we can shift a portion of our
international interdiction funds to the UN's long-term, multilateral crop substitution
efforts. Over the long-term, simultaneous, coordinated efforts at opium control might
actually reduce world supply instead of stimulating it as bilateral operations have.
3.) Given the complexity of the global drug trade, there is no bilateral, short-term,
supply-side solution to the US drug problem. Consequently, we must divert much current
drug war budget from repression to education and treatment.
4.) Since all drugs imported into the United States are somehow consumed, we should
maintain an effective Customs barrier to minimize the smuggling of illicit narcotics.
5.) As a part of this putative strategy of "regulation," we might seriously
consider "decriminalization" of narcotics possession of small quantities for
personal use or petty sales. Instead of mandatory prison terms for possession of small
amounts of drugs, reformed laws might mandate compulsory treatment, relieving the mounting
pressure on our prisons and the public purse that supports them.
6.) Under the critical review of existing drug laws that will accompany this policy of
regulation, the benefits of banning the free purchase of hypodermic syringes should be
examined. Although the policy has been in place for decades, there is little evidence that
these restrictions have in any way reduced the level of drug addiction.
7.) Rather than letting drug sales rise to their natural level through legalization or
seeking a sudden reduction in supply by short-term repression, the logic of this policy
aims for a gradual diminution in narcotics and hard drug consumption over long-term. To
avoid repeating the experience of the late 1970s when a sudden heroin shortage stimulated
domestic production of synthetic drugs, the US and UN policy should be coordinated to
affect a slow, steady decline in world opiates supply.
8.) Ultimately we must realize that there is no "quick fix" to the US drug
problem. Through this policy of regulation we can stop the American state from using its
considerable power to compound the problem. Then we can slow and stabilize the level of
domestic drug use, working over the long-term for a gradual amelioration.
II. ANALYSIS OF EPOCHS, TRENDS & CAUSALITY:
1.) Glossary of Basic Concepts:
a.) Asian Opium Zone:
As opium spread from its biotic home in the eastern Mediterranean across India to China by
the 8th Century A.D., this long historical process created the ecological foundation for a
geographically disparate, economically integrated Asian opium zone.
With the rise of the China opium trade in late 18th century and the emergence of opium as
a global commodity in the late 19th century, the Asian opium zone expanded to its maximum
area--extending from the Balkans, across India, through southern China, to Manchuria.
During the era of multilateral drug diplomacy from 1907 to 1940, the League of Nations
acted to lower production significantly within this zone. Moreover, the advent of the Cold
War and establishment of a communist regime in China in 1949, removed vast territories and
reduced the zone to its present area.
Since the late 1940s, Turkey has thus marked the western extremity of a near continuous
opium zone that stretch for 5,000 miles along the mountain rim of Asia--through Iran,
Afghanistan, Pakistan, Burma, Thailand, and Laos. Any reduction of production in a single
sector, such as Turkey, soon becomes a strong market stimulus for increased cultivation
elsewhere along the opium zone.
Although postwar US narcotics officials have operated with a de facto definition of Asia's
opium zone as a series of self-contained sectors (Middle East, South West Asia, and
Southeast Asia), this elongated highland zone has responded, over the past half century,
to stimuli from the global drug market with a surprising speed and unanimity.
In the 20th Century, the opium poppy has been introduced to Mexico, Guatemala, and
Colombia by trafficking syndicates seeking a market in the United States. Although the
climate, economy, and ecology of these regions is sympathetic to opium cultivation, the
Americas have never produced significant quantities by comparison to the Asian Opium Zone.
b.) Bilateral Suppression:
Although the US initiated and later participated in multilateral drug diplomacy, during
the past half century Washington has shown a marked preference for bilateral narcotics
operations. From its foundation in 1930, the US Federal Bureau of Narcotics (FBN), the
antecedent of the present Drug Enforcement Agency (DEA), demonstrated a predilection for
bilateral operations. The founder and long time head of the FBN, Harry Anslinger, often
attended League and UN multilateral meetings as the US representative, but he insisted
that the FBN conduct its own investigations.
After World War II, the U.S. abandoned its multilateral approach to international
suppression and extended the FBN's operations into Europe and the Middle East where it
achieved a modicum of success. In these efforts against European syndicates, the FBN
preferred bilateral enforcement, with its own agents working in cooperation with host
country police.
In 1972 the United States launched its first major attempt at bilateral suppression of the
international traffic when President Richard Nixon declared "war on drugs."
Fighting his first battle on the Anatolian plateau, Nixon, manipulating the close U.S.
military alliance with Turkey, forced that country to eradicate legal poppy growing.
Simultaneously, the US applied diplomatic pressure on Paris to close Corsican syndicate
heroin laboratories in Marseilles.
Scoring a stunning, short-term success, Nixon's drug war eliminated Corsican heroin
refining in Marseilles and ended illicit opium cultivation in Turkey. Over the long term,
however, the campaign stimulated global opium cultivation. Since demand remained constant
and supply decreased, the world price for illicit opium rose, stimulating increased
harvests elsewhere along the Asian opium zone.
Deciding that international intervention did not slow the drug flow, the Carter White
House adopted a more cautious policy. With the exception of modest operations against
opium in Mexico, Carter de-emphasized bilateral drug diplomacy.
Ignoring the lessons of Nixon's Anatolian campaign, President Bush used the same strategy
for his drug war in the Andes--a combination of diplomacy and suppression to cut the drug
flow at its source. Despite these similarities in broad strategy, Bush increased the
weaponry in the arsenal of his drug war far beyond Nixon's modest resources--most
importantly, by mobilizing the resources of the US military in support of State Department
diplomacy and CIA intelligence.
c.) Central Asia:
The term is used variously to mean the countries between the Caspian Sea and Tibet,
comprising Turkmenistan, Uzbekistan, Tajikistan, Kirghizia, Kazakhstan, Afghanistan, and,
sometimes, Iran.
d.) Golden Triangle:
A term of unknown origins, the phase "Golden Triangle" refers to a roughly
triangular zone in the highlands of Southeast Asia that overlaps Burma, Thailand, and
Laos. Although divided among three countries, it is a region that shares significant
attributes--opium production, remote upland terrain, mountain minority populations,
extreme ethnic diversity, mass Christian conversion, and a long history of insurgency. To
delineate the region, trace the China border across Burma into Laos, turn sharp west at
Xieng Khouang and track a line due west across northern Thailand to Mae Hong Son, and then
turn north and follow the length of the Salween River.
e.) Heroin:
Discovered by a British chemist in 1874 , diacetylmorphine is a bonding of opium's active
ingredient, morphine, with a common industrial acid, acetic anhydride. Twenty years later,
in 1898, when the Bayer Company of Elberfeld, Germany began mass producing the drug as a
broad-spectrum painkiller, it coined the trade name "heroin" for this new drug.
Approved by the American Medical Association in 1906, physicians administered heroin
widely with hypodermic syringe as a non-addictive substitute for morphine, a pain killer
in common use since the 1860s. Simultaneously, pharmaceutical manufacturers marketed
heroin in patent medicines as a cure for many diseases, including infantile respiratory
ailments.
Under the US Harrison Narcotics Act of 1914, all narcotics use henceforth required a
doctor's prescription. In 1923, the Narcotics Division of the Treasury Department began
active enforcement of the law, a responsibility that was transferred in 1930 to the
Federal Bureau of Narcotics (FBN), the ancestor of the modern Drug Enforcement
Administration (DEA). The net effect of these changes was to criminalize the personal use
of heroin and cocaine. In 1925, the League of Nations passed strict regulations on the
international export of heroin and six years later stipulated that manufacturers could
produce just enough for legitimate medical and scientific needs.
A powerful narcotic, heroin acts upon the brain's opiate receptors to act as a
pain-killer, inducing physical addiction and lasting psychological dependence. Unlike
marijuana or cocaine, heroin is a maintenance drug requiring daily dosage--a basic
attribute that explains its extraordinary profitability. While cocaine users often quit
use after a few months on this drug's roller-coaster ride of euphoria and depression,
heroin addicts, by contrast, continue use for many years, making them repeat customers for
criminal syndicates. Since heroin requires a daily dosage to avoid the unpleasant symptoms
of withdrawal, its users are more assiduous in their habit and more willing to pay a
premium price for the drug. Cocaine's market and profitability thus require constant
recruitment of new addicts, in contrast to heroin's patterns of long-term use that assure
a more reliable and profitable illicit market.
f.) Multilateral Suppression:
Responding to pressures from a Christian anti-opium movement in the United Kingdom and the
United States in the latter decades of the 19th Century, Western governments realized that
legal opium trading in their Asian colonies opened them to moral censure.
In 1909, a meeting of major Western and Asian governments at the Shanghai Opium Convention
marks the start of the modern era of multilateral drug diplomacy. Although this gathering
produced non-binding commitments to reduction of opium trading, it set in motion a
diplomacy that culminated, during the mid 1920s, in formation of a multilateral
"Advisory Committee on the Traffic in Opium and Other Dangerous Drugs" within
the League of Nations. Through these deliberations, the League of Nations effected, via
its member states, a significant, even dramatic, reduction in the legal production of
opium and processing of heroin between 1925 and 1940.
With the establishment of the United Nations in 1945, this committee continued its work as
the UN Committee for Drug Abuse Control. Since the ratification of the UN Single
Convention on Narcotics in 1961, its multilateral efforts have become a more significant
factor global drug controls. Through this body, the UN sponsors research into the patterns
of drug abuse in countries such as Pakistan and engages in crop substitution programs in
Laos and Thailand.
g.) Nature of Consumption Estimates:
Estimates of drug consumption may be the most politicized and inaccurate of all modern
statistics. As noted ever so wryly in a 1976 report of the House Select Committee on
Narcotics Abuse, "There is an old axiom which originated in the League of
Nations...that a nation has as many addicts as it chooses to discover."
In Western nations where intravenous use is prevalent, the only reliable drug-abuse
statistic is the number of heroin overdose fatalities actually recorded by coroners. All
other numbers are a statistical manipulation of the ratio between a known figure, such as
overdose fatalities or street seizures, and an unknown quantity, such as the number of
addicts. Simply by changing the ratio of the known to unknown, bureaucracies or
administrations can, for self-serving purposes, arbitrarily adjust estimates of drug abuse
upward or downward. Rather than say "lots of drug use" or a "huge addict
population," this report uses drug consumption figures as "descriptive
numbers."
h.) Nature of Production Estimates:
Over the past 300 years, Asia's opium-producing areas have been, almost by definition,
remote from central control and state records. Since the rise of multilateral prohibition
in the 1920s, it is this remoteness that both allows illicit opium cultivation and makes
accurate quantification of it almost impossible. Prior to the mid-19th Century, most
agricultural statistics, opium included, are erratic, anecdotal, and unverified. Although
reporting for major commodities in lowland areas improved dramatically in the late 19th
century, hill crops such as opium usually remained beyond the purview of enumerators.
Since the 1960s, narcotics statistics have suffered from a mix of political bias and
technical problems. All host countries reporting their own drug production have a vested
interest in minimization, while foreign analysts are usually involved in enforcement
efforts and have a different but equally strong bias in skewing the numbers for some
bureaucratic end. In its April 1994 report, the US State Department stated that
Afghanistan's production in 1992 was "officially" 640 tons but noted that the
DEA felt that country's opium output was "may have exceeded 900 tons." Whether
this difference was based on honest disagreement or different agency agendas, the reader
can only guess. In this same report, the State Department estimates Burma's 1993 harvest
at 2,575 tons, yet that same month the country's leading drug lord, Khun Sa, told me that
production was actually 4,000 tons. Even in this age of technologically advanced landsat
imaging, the US State Department Report for 1990 estimates Southwest Asia's actual opium
production for 1987 as ranging from 790 to 1,420 tons. What is any analyst supposed to
make of such numbers?
In recording each production figure, this report has been aware of the acute problems
inherent in modern opium statistics. Instead of saying "lots of opium" or
"huge amounts of heroin," the report has cited these sometimes questionable
statistics. Instead of taking them at face value, we suggest that production figures be
regarded as "descriptive numbers" rather than statistics accurate in the
conventional sense.
i.) Opium:
Domesticated in the eastern Mediterranean in ancient times, opium is one of the most
venerable drugs in formal and folk pharmacopoeia. Opium's healing properties were detailed
in the works of Hippocrates (466-377 BC) and the Roman physician Galen (130-200 AD.)
Spreading across the Asian land mass, opium was described as an effective drug in China's
Herbalist Treasure of 973 AD.
As a temperate crop, the opium poppy (papaver soniferum) cannot prosper in warm climates
and has thus been grown in tropical Asia at cooler elevations in excess of 3,000 feet
above sea level. In these regions, the poppy is usually found in mountains at the margin
of nation states where it has often merged with ethnic insurgency or international
conflict.
At its furthest extent in the early 1900s, farmers cultivated opium across a broad swath
of the Eurasian land mass stretching from the Balkans; across Turkey, Persia, and India;
to China and Manchuria. Since World War II, however, illicit opium cultivation has been
confined to a 5,000 mile band of mountains stretching from Turkey to Laos.
By incising the head of the opium poppy, traditional farmers can extract its sticky brown
sap from the egg-shaped bulb. Before processing into morphine base or heroin, the raw
opium sap contains 7 to 15 percent morphine, the active drug, by weight. While morphine is
easily precipitated from the poppy sap after simple boiling, the manufacture of heroin, a
compound of morphine and an industrial acid, is a more complex chemical process.
Opium's survival as a recreational and medical drug for over 4,000 years seems to arise
from its interaction with the human brain. Since the discovery of opiate receptors in the
brain during the 1970s, there has been "a major advance in our understanding of the
molecular substrates of addiction"--establishing, to put it simply, that opiate
addiction is physiological, not simply psychological. Recent neurobiological research has
found "clear evidence for intrinsic mechanisms of opiate dependence and withdrawal in
the locus coeruleus." Since opiates induce chronic "changes in brain
function," there are identifiable physical syndromes of opiate addiction and
withdrawal.
In effect, the functioning of opium receptors in the human brain render most repeat or
chronic users liable to lasting physical addiction, giving the global opiates market some
unique attributes. Combing the nuerobiological with the economic allows us to identify
these attributes of opium as a commodity: (1.) the predisposition of humans to opiate
addiction guarantees a ready market for any supplier; (2.) physiological addiction creates
a stable clientele of addicts that usually grows rapidly as new users join old, with few
of either quitting; (3.) addicts' need for a daily dosage of the drug to avoid withdrawal
assures suppliers a reliable, high volume market of consumers who will place a primacy
upon meeting their opiate needs.
In effect, opium combines the high price of a luxury good with the steady, almost
inelastic, demand of a dietary staple, allowing it an unequaled profitability. Opiates
addiction is, in sum, a natural physiological state, and addicts will pay any price to
maintain the level of extrinsic opiates in their system. There is then no human activity
more profitable opium marketing, allowing its entrepreneurs an extraordinary level of
profit and political power.
j.) Opiate Epoch:
Unlike the rise and fall of rulers or their empires, the delineation of eras or epochs of
opium production cannot be done with any real chronological precision. While the birth of
a king or the capture of a capital have tidy dates, the complex economic and social
processes involved in the production of a commodity like opium are far less palpable.
Within this imprecise exercise, we can nonetheless track broad historical trends, using
quantitative indices and qualitative factors to discern both aspects of continuity and
points of discontinuity in the world opium trade. Sometimes a major event, like the Second
Opium War in 1858 or the fall of China in 1949, has such a far reaching impact that it
serves to mark an historical watershed between commodity epochs. At other times, a cluster
of variables--economic, political, social, and religious--combine to produce changes in
supply or demand of opium so significant that they too mark a watershed between epochs of
global opium production.
k.) Opium as Commodity:
As two leading American anthropologists, Sidney Mintz and Eric Wolf, have taught us, the
modern commerce in commodities involves much more than mere economic exchange. Since the
rise of the modern world economy, commodities have--in a fundamental sense--shaped the
politics, culture, and social structure of peoples around the globe. Concluding his study
of sugar's modern social history, Mintz comments: "The first sweetened cup of hot tea
to be drunk by an English worker was a significant historical event, because it prefigured
the transformation of an entire society, a total remaking of its economic and social
basis." Similarly, from the late 18th century onwards, opium became a key commodity
in the expanding commerce between Asia and the Atlantic nations, thereby becoming enmeshed
in the economies and cultures of both regions.
Above all, it is opium's long history as a global commodity that has given its traffic a
unique and little understood dynamic. During the 18th century, when it first emerged as a
commodity, opium production grew as one part of a rising long-distance trade in natural
stimulants--coffee, tea, tobacco, and coca--that tied First World consumers and Third
World producers together in a global commerce. As demand for opiates rose in the 19th
century, opium cultivation spread across the Eurasian land mass from Yugoslavia to
Manchuria. Simultaneously, the pharmaceutical manufacture of opium products developed in
the world's industrial centers.
By the time the United Nations adopted its Single Convention prohibiting all non-medicinal
opiate use in 1961, the trade in legal stimulants--coffee, tea, and tobacco--ranked among
the top 20 of the world's commodities with petroleum, wheat, and cotton. Although precise
statistics are not available, there are indications that opium would have ranked equally
high had such a list been compiled in 1906 when global drug supply reached its historic
peak. In short, by the time prohibition efforts started, opium was already established as
a major global commodity with the economic scale, social ramifications, and political
support to resist any reduction of such a vital trade.
l.) South West Asia:
Like the term "Golden Triangle," the phrase "South West Asia" has been
coined to describe a zone of contemporary conflict that straddles conventional
geographical divisions. During the 1980s, the Afghan war and the rise of heroin production
in Afghanistan and Pakistan forced the coining of this neologism. Since Afghanistan is
generally considered part of Central Asia and Pakistan integral to South Asia, there was a
need to delineate a region unified by Islamic political issues, anti-Soviet insurgency,
and opium trading. Instead of the popular term "Golden Crescent," the phrase
"South West Asia" is used in this report for Iran, Afghanistan, and Pakistan.
2.) Opium as Folk Pharmacopoeia (Up to 1600):
a.) Summary of Text in "Politics of Heroin" (pp. 3-4, 77-79):
Regardless of level of development, most societies have used drugs for religion,
recreation, and medicine. Discovered and domesticated during prehistoric times in the
Mediterranean basin, opium became a trade item between Cyprus and Egypt sometime in the
second millennium B.C. The drug first appeared in Greek pharmacopoeia during the 5th
Century B.C. and in Chinese medical texts during the 8th century A.D. Inferring from such
slender evidence, it appears that opium farming first developed in the eastern
Mediterranean and spread gradually along Asia's trade routes to India, reaching China by
the eighth century A.D. Once introduced into China, opium gained a significant role in
formal pharmacopoeia.
It was not until the 15th Century that residents of Persia and India began consuming opium
mixtures as a purely recreational euphoric, a practice that made opium a major item in an
expanding intra-Asian trade. Indeed, under the reign of Akbar (1556-1605), the Mughal
state of north India relied upon opium land as a significant source of revenue. Although
cultivation covered the whole Mughal empire, it was concentrated in two main
areas--upriver from Calcutta along the Ganges Valley for "Bengal opium" and
upcountry from Bombay in the west for "Malwa opium."
b.) Summary and Analysis of Trends within Epoch:
The persistent role of opiates as folk medicine and recreational euphoric for nearly 4,000 years raises very real questions about the enormous difficulties in effecting its eradication. Through interaction with opiate receptors in the brain, opium and heroin may well have an inherent biological logic that makes their mass abuse a likelihood at most times, in most societies, where ample supply of the drug is available. Historically, every society that has been introduced to opium as a commercial euphoric has consumed the entire supply made available to it.
3.) Early European Opium Trade (1640-1773):
a.) Summary of Text in "Politics of Heroin" (pp. 4, 78-80):
The earliest European expeditions to Asia also mark the start of their involvement in
the region's opium trade. As Portuguese captains first ventured across the Indian Ocean
during the early 16th century, they realized the potential of opium. "If your
Highness would believe me," Affonso de Albuquerque, the conqueror of Malacca, wrote
to his monarch from India in 1513, "I would order poppies...to be sown in all the
fields of Portugal and command afyam [opium] to be made...and the laborers would gain much
also, and people of India are lost without it, if they do not eat it.." From their
ports in western India, the Portuguese began exporting Malwa opium to China, competing
aggressively with Indian and Arab merchants who controlled this trade.
Eager for a commodity to barter for Chinese silks, the Portuguese imported tobacco from
their Brazilian colony half a world away. Although the Chinese frustrated the Portuguese
by growing their own tobacco, the pipe itself, which had been introduced by the Spanish,
turned out to be the key to China's markets. Indian opium, mixed with tobacco and smoked
through a pipe, was somehow pleasing to the Chinese palate. By the early 18th century,
opium smoking was spreading across China, prompting the empire's first attempt at
suppression in 1729 when the Emperor Yung Cheng issued an edict banning the smoking of
opium.
Arriving in Asia a century after the Portuguese, the Dutch soon became active in the
region's opium commerce. Instead of trading directly with China like the Portuguese, the
Dutch established a permanent port at Jakarta in 1619 and began purchasing opium from
Bengal in 1640 to supply Java's limited demand. As Dutch colonials won monopoly rights for
Java's populous districts, their Company's opium imports from India rose dramatically from
617 kilograms in 1660 to 72,280 kilograms only 25 years later. Dutch profits from the
opium trade were spectacular. Buying opium cheap in India and selling high in Java allowed
the Company a 400 percent profit on shipments in the 1670s. Opium, moreover, proved to be
a key trade good that drew Asian merchants to Jakarta. By 1681, opium represented 34
percent of the cargo on Asian ships sailing out of Jakarta. No longer a lightweight luxury
or medical item, opium was on its way to becoming a commodity.
Although the last of the Europeans to enter the trade, it was the British who finally
completed the transformation of opium from luxury good into bulk commodity. The British
East India Company had acquired coastal enclaves at Calcutta in 1656 and Bombay in 1661,
but it did not become a major factor in the opium trade for another century. In the
interim, a syndicate of Indian merchants up the Ganges River at Patna held a monopoly over
the "Bengal" opium trade, making cash advances to peasant farmers and selling
the processed opium to Dutch, British and French merchants. Marching inland from their
port at Calcutta, the British conquered Bengal in 1764 and soon discovered the financial
potential of India's richest opium zone.
b.) Causality underlying above changes:
In this period, the major change involved a shift from a limited trade in opium though
intra-Asian networks to an expanding European commerce that stimulated both supply and
demand. In the 16th century and earlier, there had been a pre-existing, modest demand for
opium in China and Southeast Asia, and low-level production of opium in India. Working
separately, European mercantile companies commercialized both opium cultivation and
commerce, making it the basis of a profitable long distance trade in low-weight,
high-value goods. At first, the Portuguese transported Indian opium to China. Then the
Spanish developed a way to mix tobacco with opium so it could be smoked. Finally, the
Dutch took advantage of this rising demand for opium, but their main market was limited to
Java and some re-export to China. Through these European efforts, the problem of opium
addiction became so serious in China that the Emperor had it banned in 1729.
The extraordinary profitability of this low-weight, high-value commodity was a key
incentive for escalating European involvement in the Asian opium trade. In particular, the
Dutch V.O.C. made a 400 percent profit on its 1679 shipments.
c.) Statistical Evidence from Text & Sources, "Politics of Heroin":
1.) Increase/decrease in World Opium Production:
--Dutch East India Company (VOC) imports from India rose at a rate of 1.5 per annum during the 1660s--rising from 0.6 metric tons in 1660 to 72.3 tons only 25 years later.
--In 1699, the Dutch imported 87 tons of Indian opium for distribution to Java and the Indies.
--British exports of Indian opium to China increased from 15 tons in 1720 to 75 tons in 1773.
2.) Changes in Opium Cultivation by Region:
Indian production increased by unknown amounts in response to stimulus of European and Indian opium traders.
3.) Changes in Quantity of Opium Consumption by Region:
For the first time in its history, China experienced a significant, but unquantified, level of mass opium addiction.
d.) Summary and Analysis of Trends within Epoch:
1.) In this period, opium entered a proto-modern phase in which its capacity for growth
as a major commodity first became evident. Significantly, European and Indian merchants
played a catalytic role in commercializing and expanding the India-China opium trade.
2.) It is during this era that opium's extraordinarily profitability becomes manifest.
Through its peculiar properties, opium is the ideal trade good during this epoch. As an
addictive drug, opium requires a daily dose giving it the inelastic demand of a basic
foodstuff. Long distance sea-trade in bulk foods was beyond the capacity of current
maritime technology, but opium had the low weight and high mark-up of a luxury good like
cloves or pepper. In the early modern era, opium combines the reliable demand of a basic
food with the logistics of a luxury good. Compounding its profitability, the Chinese
emperor reacted to the rise of mass addiction by banning opium and thus denying China the
opportunity to produce opium locally to undercut the high price of Indian imports.
4.) Era of European Mercantilism (1773-1858):
a.) Summary of Text in "Politics of Heroin" (pp. 80-89):
The modern era in the global opium trade began in 1773 when the British
Governor-General of Bengal established a monopoly on the sale of opium. Over the next 130
years, Britain actively promoted the export of Indian opium, defying Chinese drug laws and
fighting two wars to open China's drug market for its merchants. Under the British, Indian
opium became a major global commodity, giving this modern commerce a scale and
organization that distinguishes it from earlier forms.
When the East India Company conquered Bengal, it took control of a well-established opium
industry involving peasant producers, merchants, and long-distance traders. In 1773, the
British Governor abolished the Indian opium syndicate at Patna and established a colonial
monopoly on principles that operated for the next half-century. Under the new regulations,
the Company had the exclusive right to purchase opium from Bengal's farmers and auction it
for export. Realizing that opium was illegal in China, the Governor barred the Company's
ships that called at Canton to load tea from carrying opium, leaving actual sale of the
addictive drug to the private European merchants who bid at the Company's Calcutta
auctions.
In 1797 the Company eliminated the local opium buyers in Bengal and established a system
of direct collection that lasted for over a century. Under the new procedures, the
Company, and the colonial state that succeeded it, controlled opium cultivation,
processing, and export. At its peak in the late 19th century, Bengal's opium country
stretched for 500 miles across the Ganges River Valley, with over a million registered
farmers growing poppy plants exclusively for the company on some 500,000 acres of prime
land. From their factories at Patna and Benares in the heart of opium country, senior
British officers directed some 2,000 Indian agents who circulated through the poppy
districts, extending credit and collecting opium. Processed under strict supervision at
the two Company factories, the opium was packed into wooden chests, each containing forty
balls and weighing 140 pounds. Bearing the "Patna" and "Benares"
trade-marks, the chests were sent down to Calcutta under guard and sold at auction to
private British merchants.
Since the Chinese state had damned opium as a "destructive and ensnaring vice"
and banned all imports in 1799, British sea captains bribed Canton's mandarins and
smuggled the chests into southern China where the Bengal brands commanded twice the price
of the inferior local products. For its first quarter century, this system assured
prosperity for British India and a stable opium supply for China. Not only did opium solve
the fiscal crisis that accompanied the British conquest of Bengal, it remained a staple of
colonial finances, providing from six to fifteen percent of British India's tax revenues
during the 19th Century.
More importantly, opium exports were an essential component of a "triangular
trade" that was central to England's position as a world power. Trade figures for the
1820s, for example, show that the triangular trade was large and well balanced: 22 million
pounds sterling worth of Indian opium and cotton to China; next, 20 million pounds worth
of Chinese tea to Britain; and, then, 24 million pounds of British textiles and machinery
back to India. In managing this trade, the Company prized stability above profit, and for
over twenty years it held India's opium exports at 4,000 chests--or 280 tons, just enough
to finance its purchase of China's tea crop.
The system's success was the cause of its downfall. The vast profits of the Britain's
opium trade attracted competitors. Moreover, the Company's steadfast refusal to raise
Bengal's opium exports beyond the quota of 4,000 chests per annum left a vast unmet demand
for drugs among China's swelling population of opium smokers. As demand drove the price
per chest upward from 415 rupees in 1799 to 2,428 rupees just 15 years later, the
Company's monopoly on Bengal opium faced strong competition from Turkey and west India.
Britain's most daring rivals were the Americans. Barred from bidding at the Calcutta
auctions, Yankee traders loaded their first cargoes of Turkish opium at Smyrna in 1805 and
sailed them around the tip of Africa to China. Through these efforts, Turkish opium
remained an alternative to the Bengal brands until 1834 when the Yankee captains were
finally allowed to bid at the Calcutta auctions and abandoned the long haul around Africa.
The major threat to the Company's monopoly, however, came from Malwa opium grown in the
princely states of west India. Malwa opium captured 40 percent of the China market by
1811. Determined to defend their trade, the Company's directors decided to promote
unlimited production in Bengal. In 1831 the Governor-General of India, Lord William
Bentinck, toured the upper Ganges with revenue officers to explore new areas for poppy
farming and within the decade cultivation doubled to 176,000 acres.
After the East India Company lost its charter in 1834, its informal regulation of the
China opium trade collapsed, allowing profit-hungry American and British captains to take
control. Indeed, the Company's demise launched a fleet of new "opium clippers"
to tack to China against the monsoon winds. As the Company loosened its restrictions in
the 1820s and then lost its monopoly in 1834, China's opium imports increased nearly ten
fold--from 270 tons in 1820 to 2,558 tons twenty years later. Opium addiction spread
rapidly, reaching some three million Chinese addicts by the 1830s.
In defense of its commerce, Britain fought two wars along the China coast in 1842 and
1858, forcing the empire to open itself to unrestricted opium imports. In 1838, the
Emperor's launched a moralistic anti-opium campaign that threatened Britain's China trade,
and London dispatched a fleet of six warships, capturing Canton in May 1839. The First
Opium war ended in 1842 with the Treaty of Nanking which required China to cede Hong Kong,
and open five new ports to foreign trade. But China still refused to legalize opium.
The fifteen years following the First Opium War brought a new peak in the China trade.
Illicit imports of Indian opium nearly doubled, rising to 4,810 tons in 1858. At the
Calcutta auctions, frenzied bidding drove opium prices and profits to new heights, making
a fast run to the China coast essential and launching 48 new clippers for the opium fleet.
Among the 95 clippers in the fleet, the Calcutta's Cowasjee family owned six, the
Americans of Russell & Co. had eight, and the British giants, Dent and Jardine,
operated a total of 27.
The era of the opium clipper ended when China finally legalized the drug trade after its
defeat in the Second Opium War (1856-1858). In negotiations over the tariff provisions of
this new treaty that ended the war, the British emissary Lord Elgin forced the Chinese to
legalize opium imports. In the aftermath of legalization, Chinese officials began
encouraging local production, and poppy cultivation spread beyond the country's southwest.
As addiction spread throughout China, imports of Indian opium rose from 4,800 tons in 1859
to 6,700 tons twenty years later. After peaking in 1880, Indian imports declined slowly
for the rest of the century as cheaper, China-grown opium began to supplant the high-grade
Bengal brands.
b.) Causality underlying above changes:
1.) Demand Increasing Ahead of Production:
It appears that opium, once commercialized as recreational euphoric, produces a
disproportionate demand that soon exceeds the original supply. In this case, the carefully
controlled number of chests from Bengal soon proved insufficient for the demand in China.
The result was stimulation of production in other opium regions. Thus, Malwa and Turkish
production increased to help meet China's growing demand. In the end, England capitulated
to market pressures, abandoned its self-imposed restraint, and encouraged an expansion of
opium production in India.
Once introduced, commercial opium stimulated demand in China beyond supply, encouraging
thereby increased cultivation back in India; which, in turn, stimulated more demand in
China, sparking, yet again, higher poppy plantings in India. In effect, even in this
earliest era of commoditized opium trading, demand and supply increase through a process
of reciprocal stimulation that makes it difficult, analytically, to determine which is the
dominant cause. During the 18th and 19th Centuries, China had a limitless capacity for
opium consumption that continually outstripped all production, both local and global.
2.) Changes in Shipping Technology:
Since there was now an unlimited amount of opium that could be grown in India,
improvements in shipping technology were needed to move greater amounts to China. Hence, a
competition and the appearance of the clipper ship. Speed now determined profitability in
the opium trade.
3.) Chinese Government Policy:
The Chinese Imperial decrees of 1729 and 1799 banning opium smoking and importation did
not restrain the rising addiction problem. However, the legalization of opium consumption
in 1858 encouraged a sharp rise in both production and consumption. With legalization,
domestic opium superseded imports, making speed less important in the shipping of opium
and allowing steamships to replace the clippers.
Thus, we must conclude that China's policy of prohibiting opium consumption and
cultivation from 1729 to 1858 assured the East India Company a de facto monopoly over this
fast growing market and created the basic underlying conditions for the hyper
profitability of the India-China opium trade. Without this prohibition on cultivation,
China could have reacted the Company's aggressive exports of Bengal opium by encouraging
local opium harvests and destroying both market and profits for the Indian imports. As it
was, China's addicts and their near insatiable demand for the illicit drug created high
profits and inspired ferocious competition among merchant captains competing for a share
of this lucrative market--English out of Calcutta, Indian and English out of Bombay, and
Americans out of Smyrna, Turkey.
4.) Nature of Chinese Demand: In the midst of the acute demographic and caloric crisis of southeastern China in the late 18th and early 19th Centuries, opium attributes as a appetite suppressant may have increased its appeal to users at a time of scarcity and high food prices. At certain periods, the use of opium may have suppressed appetite sufficiently to make its addiction economical in comparison to the cost of eating a normal diet.
5.) Economics of European Mercantilism: In colonial Asia of this period (1773-1858),
all successful European economic initiatives involved commercialization of drugs in some
form--caffeine, nicotine, or opiates. This 18th century trade transformed these drugs from
luxury goods into commodities of mass consumption, making them integral to the economies
and lifestyles of both Asian and Atlantic nations.
In Java after 1720, the Dutch V.O.C. collected a tax in coffee in the Priangen region of
west Java and made vast profits through sales in Europe and America, becoming the globe's
greatest coffee broker and gaining thereby a substitute for its substantial share of the
China opium trade lost to Britain after 1720.
Consciously imitating the V.O.C., Bourbon Spanish reformers in Manila established the
Tobacco Monopoly in the 1782 and, for the next century, financed their colonial
administration from their exclusive control over the cultivation and sale of this
addictive drug to Filipinos.
In Bengal, the British East India Company imposed a monopoly over opium in 1773 and used
its sale to China to finance purchase of caffeine, in the form of tea, for export to
Europe and North America. Within the monopolistic logic of mercantilism, the East India
Company achieved the highest profits from opium because, from 1773 to 1830, its strong
controls over key aspects--production, export, and sales.
c.) Statistical Evidence from Text & Sources, "Politics of Heroin":
1.) Increase/decrease in World Opium Production:
--The area under cultivation in Bengal, India increased from 90,000 acres in 1830, to 176,000 by 1840, and, finally, a peak of 500,000 acres by 1900.
2.) Changes in Opium Cultivation by Region:
--Reflecting directly increases in production, Indian opium exports to China rose from 75 tons in 1773 to 4,810 tons in 1858--a sustained, high-level of growth over the space of 75 years.
--Again reflecting increases in production, Turkish exports to China increased from 7 tons in 1805 to 100 tons in 1830--creating another instance of steady, high-level growth in production over a protracted period.
3.) Changes in Quantity of Opium Consumption by Region:
--Rising from insignificant levels in the early 1700s, by the 1830s China had an estimated 3 million opium smokers.
--US imports of opium rose 8 tons in 1840 to 62.7 tons in 1858.
d.) Summary and Analysis of Trends within Epoch:
From the late 18th century onward, opium became a major trade commodity. Under the
British East India Company (BEIC), centralized controls accelerated the export of Indian
opium to China--from 13 tons in 1729 to and 2,558 tons in 1839. Using its full military
and mercantile power, Britain played a central role in making China a lucrative drug
market.
The Company's steadfast refusal to raise Bengal's opium exports beyond its self-imposed
quota of 4,000 chests per annum left a vast unmet demand for drugs among China's swelling
population of opium smokers. When demand drove the price per chest upward from 415 rupees
in 1799 to 2,428 rupees just 15 years later, the East India Company's monopoly on Bengal
opium faced competition from Turkey and west India.
As the Company loosened its restrictions in the 1820s and then lost its monopoly in 1834,
China's opium imports increased nearly ten fold--from 270 tons in 1820 to 2,558 tons
twenty years later. Opium addiction grew rapidly, reaching some three million Chinese
addicts by the 1830s. Simultaneously, China's illicit imports of Indian opium nearly
doubled, rising to 4,810 tons in 1858.
5.) High Imperial Opium Trade (1858-1907):
a.) Summary of Text in "Politics of Heroin" (pp. 89-96):
During the latter half of the 19th century, opium became a major global commodity.
Across the Asian opium zone, from the Balkans to Manchuria, there was a steady increase of
local opium cultivation and consumption. Moreover, in the latter half of the 19th century,
the modern pharmaceutical industry made opiates a drug of mass abuse in the cities of the
West--Europe, the Americas, and Australia. By the early 20th century, opium and its
derivatives, morphine and heroin, had become a major global commodity equivalent in scale
to other drugs such as coffee and tea.
In retrospect, the growth of mass narcotics abuse in the West seems part of the
transformation of diet and health care in the late 19th century. In an era when Western
medicine had still not developed genuine therapeutic remedies, self-medication with opium
and the profession's reliance on morphine injection encouraged drug abuse. Indeed, opium
was a genuinely effective against the gastrointestinal diseases that were epidemic in the
cities of 19th Century England and America. Introduced to skeptical American doctors in
1856, the hypodermic syringe proved an effective means of relieving pain with morphine
injection, and by 1881 many physicians used the drug as a panacea for wide range of
illness. With the approval of the medical profession, Western pharmaceutical manufacturers
such as Bayer and Parke-Davis began selling substantial quantities of opiates and coca in
the form of popular remedies. Such successful marketing made mass addiction to cocaine and
heroin a significant feature of late 19th century life in the West. Soon after the Bayer
Company introduced heroin as a non-addictive substitute for morphine in 1898, the American
Medical Association (AMA), continuing the profession's long reliance on opiate
medications, initially endorsed the new drug as safe for respiratory ailments.
The spread of mass addiction was part of a new diet in the industrial nations based on a
global trade in proteins and stimulants. After a century of constant dietary habits, the
average Englishman's consumption of sugar, jumped four-fold from 1850 to 1900. During the
same period, England's per capita consumption of tea increased three-fold. Similarly, in
the United States between 1865 and 1902 coffee consumption increased nearly three-fold,
while sugar jumped four-fold. The simple 18th century diet of milled grains had given way
to one spiced with large quantities of protein (eggs and beef), glucose (sugar), and
stimulants (coffee and tea).
If an energized diet of proteins, glucose and caffeine could be used to stimulate the body
through a long working day, then narcotic-based medicines could be used to relax it in the
short hours of rest. Paralleling the growth of sugar and coffee use, American consumption
of opium rose over four-fold from the 1840s to the 1890s, and the number of addicts peaked
at 313,000 in 1896. In the United Kingdom, sales of patent medicines, most of them
opium-based, increased almost seven-fold between 1850 and 1905. Significantly, the average
consumption of opium per 1,000 population increased from 1.3 pounds in 1827 to over 10
pounds 50 years later.
Reflecting and reinforcing these global changes, the legalization of opium in China
quickly transformed the country into the world's leading producer. After the Second Opium
War ended in 1858, Chinese officials encouraged local production, and poppy cultivation
spread beyond the southwest to nearly every province. As addiction rose throughout China,
imports of Indian opium increased from 4,800 tons in 1859 to an historic high of 6,700
tons in 1879. Despite the growth of Indian imports after 1858, most of the higher demand
was supplied by Chinese domestic production.
By the 1880s, China was in the midst of a major opium boom, particularly in the rugged
southwestern provinces of Szechwan and Yunnan. Observers claimed that China's leading
opium producing province, Szechwan, was harvesting 10,000 tons of raw opium annually. In
1881, the British consul at Yichang estimated the total opium production in the southwest
at 13,525 tons, a figure that at first seemed exaggerated. Twenty-five years later,
however, the first official statistics showed that Szechwan and Yunnan were in fact
producing 19,100 tons, equivalent to 54 percent of China's total harvest. Although
estimates varied widely, by 1885 China was probably growing twice as much opium as it was
importing. By 1906, China had 13.5 million addicts consuming some 39,000 tons of opium.
With bountiful supplies and legal retail sales, China had 27 percent of its adult males
addicted to opium--a level of mass addiction never equaled by any nation before or since.
During the 19th century, Southeast Asia experienced a confluence of socio-economic
forces--demand, supply, and state policy--that expanded its total opium trade and the
degree of European dominance. First, Chinese migration to Southeast Asia accelerated the
demand for drugs throughout the 19th century, creating a substantial market of wage
laborers with the means and motivation for opium smoking. Pressed for revenues to finance
public works, European colonial governments established opium farms and leased these
revenue contracts to overseas Chinese merchants.
No mere vice, opium became a major factor in Southeast Asia's economic growth in both
public and private sectors, reflecting and reinforcing the region's ongoing modernization.
In many parts of 19th century Southeast Asia, the opium franchises were integral to the
rise of overseas Chinese capital.
In the late 19th century, these franchises gave way to state-licensed opium dens that
became a unique Southeast Asian institution, spreading and sustaining addiction throughout
the region. At first, the region's colonial governments had restricted their role to
importing the opium from India and auctioned "opium farms," or franchises, to
the highest bidder, usually a consortium of Chinese. In 1881, however, the French
administration in Saigon established the Opium Regie, a direct state marketing monopoly
that showed greater profitability. By century's turn, every Southeast Asian state, from
Burma to the Philippines, had either an opium monopoly or an officially licensed
franchise. In 1930, for example, Southeast Asia had 6,441 government opium dens that
served 272 tons of opium to 542,100 registered smokers. In no other region of the world
did so many governments promote mass drug abuse.
Dutch opium commerce on Java fostered both a vast state enterprise and a large illicit
traffic. From 1640 to 1799, the Dutch East India Company (V.O.C.) imported an average of
56 tons of opium annually, large quantities for their day that rose steadily throughout
the 19th century to 208 tons by 1904. By starting their retail monopoly two centuries
before the other European powers, the Dutch developed a large clientele of native Javanese
opium smokers. Despite efforts to reduce sales, the Dutch monopoly was still operating
1,065 opium dens in 1929 that retailed 59 tons of opium to 101,000 registered smokers.
While opium addiction weakened the local populations, it strengthened the finances of
colonial governments. In 1905-1906, for example, opium sales provided 16 percent of taxes
for French Indochina, 16 percent for the Netherlands Indies, 20 percent for Siam, and 53
percent for British Malaya. Despite heavy opium consumption, Southeast Asia did not become
a significant opium producer until the 1950s, a full century after China. Afraid that
smuggling from their remote tribal highlands would undercut high official prices, the
state monopolies did everything possible to discourage local opium production. Although
poppy cultivation did spread somewhat in the highlands during the decades before World War
II, the region still remained a minor producer. Finding even this level of cultivation
troublesome, Burma, Thailand and Indochina mounted suppression operations that reduced
region's production to only 15.5 tons in 1940--far from the Golden Triangle's 3,050 ton
harvest a half century later.
b.) Statistics from Sources & Text for "Politics of Heroin":
1.) Increase/decrease in World Opium Production:
--In 1907, the first systematic survey of opium indicated that world production stood at 41,624 tons--over ten times the 1994 world illicit opium supply.
2.) Changes in Opium Cultivation by Region:
--Rising from low levels in the 1840s, China produced 35,000 tons of raw opium in 1906-07--equivalent to 85 percent of world opium supply.
--Reflecting changes in production levels, Indian opium exports to China rose from 4,810 tons in 1858 to peak at 6,700 tons in 1879. Thereafter, Indian exports dropped by half to 3,368 tons by 1905, and then dwindled to insignificant amounts after 1913.
--Of the 41,624 tons produced worldwide, Southeast Asia produced 2 tons; Southwest Asia (Turkey, Iran, India, Afghanistan) 6,258 tons; and China 35,364 tons.
3.) Changes in Quantity of Opium Consumption by Region:
--The number of opium smokers in China increased from 3 million in the 1830s to 13.5 in 1906.
--US opiate addicts increased from low levels in the 1840s to a historic high of 313,000 by 1896.
--US imports of all opium increased dramatically from 32.8 tons in 1859 to 298.1 tons in 1907.
--Average American consumption of opium increased four-fold from 12 grains per person in the 1840s to 52 grains in the 1890s.
c.) Summary and Analysis of Trends within Epoch:
During this period of high imperialism (1858-1907), Britain loses the near monopoly
over the Asian opium trade that it enjoyed under mercantilism and the drug becomes, for
the first time in its history, a free-market commodity. Traded in mass volume through
unrestricted trade, opium gains new markets in the West and expands its trade in Asia.
To maintain profits and tax revenues, European colonial regimes in establish state opium
monopolies throughout Southeast Asia in the 1880s and 1890s, continuing an element of the
restrictive mercantilism prevalent in an earlier epoch. While controls remain over opium
sales within the colonies, its international trade is now unrestricted. In Asia, China
removes its ban on opium cultivation and thereby undercuts the hyper-profitability of
British exports. Now fully commoditized, opium spreads beyond its Asian trade axis to
become, through the modern pharmaceutical industry, a major item of mass consumption in
the West. Driven by this global commerce, world opium production reaches an historic peak
of 41,000 tons in 1907--10 times its level in 1993.
6.) Multilateral Control & Syndicate Crime (1907-1940):
a.) Summary of Text in "Politics of Heroin" (pp. 97-113,263-68):
In the late 19th century, a Christian crusade, through skillful propaganda and
lobbying, transformed itself from a populist movement into a novel form of drug diplomacy
that continues today under the United Nations. Led by Protestant clergy and laity, a
global anti-opium movement created mass support for the imposition of legal controls over
individual drug abuse, culminating in a series of treaties that restricted the global
narcotics trade. Starting with the Shanghai Opium Commission of 1909 and the International
Opium Conference at The Hague in 1911-1912, these early meetings led to a succession of
opium control treaties under the League of Nations in 1925 and the United Nations after
1945.
On balance, the most profound and lasting legacy of this movement remains the underlying
concept of applying the force of law and police to regulate what individuals do to and
with their own bodies. The intrusion of the state into a realm previously thought personal
and private marks a small but still significant watershed in modern political history.
As the anti-opium movement grew at century's turn, narcotics were already a global
commodity that sustained heavy opiates abuse in China, Europe, and America. With an addict
population representing over a quarter of the country's adult males, opium had become a
staple of the China's consumer economy. Moreover, during the late 19th century the steady
rise of mass opiates addiction in England and America added a new dimension to the global
drug trade, forming a resilient commercial connection between Asian opium growers and
Western consumers.
Launched when the drug was already a major commodity, the anti-opium movement's goal of a
total prohibition produced a contradictory legacy. The movement did force governments to
cease active promotion of drug use through licensed dens or patent medicine sales.
Paralleling these prohibition efforts, however, new criminal syndicates quickly emerged in
the major cities of Asia and the West to organize a global traffic in illicit drugs.
Between 1895 and 1910, moreover, medical opinion within the U.S. turned against the mass
prescription of opiates. From the 1870s onward, a growing number of doctors in both the
United Kingdom and the United States documented the dangers of addiction from repeated
opiate use. Moreover, research into bacteriology discovered the causes of previously
incurable diseases, thereby discouraging the use of broad-spectrum palliatives. In a sharp
reversal of past practice, in 1920 the AMA passed a resolution recommending the
prohibition of heroin.
The early anti-opium movement began as a loose alliance between British Protestants, China
missionaries, and Chinese imperial officials. Formed in 1874, the "Anglo-Oriental
Society for the Suppression of the Opium Trade" soon attracted the patronage of the
Archbishop of Canterbury. For 30 years Britain's missionaries and moralists fought a
relentless campaign that culminated in 1906 when Parliament passed a motion to end India's
opium exports. With strong mandates for suppression, a year later British and Chinese
diplomats agreed on a ten-year, step-by-step reduction in both Indian imports and Chinese
cultivation.
When Britain finally abandoned its advocacy of the Asian drug trade in 1907, opium had
become a global commodity comparable in scale to the commerce in stimulants such as coffee
and tea. Representing about 85 percent of world production, China's opium harvest of
35,000 tons sustained 13.5 million addicts, or a quarter of its adult male population.
After the revolution of 1911, China's new Republican government proved corrupt and its
opium suppression campaign faltered. China's poppy cultivation revived, morphine and
heroin pills appeared as substitutes for smoking opium, and the new Republic's cabinet was
found taking a bribe from an opium syndicate. Nonetheless, in January 1919, the Republic
burned the last chest of Indian opium at a public ritual before invited guests at
Shanghai. After more than 300 years, the India-China opium trade had ended.
While Britain engaged in bilateral negotiations with China, the United States sought a
solution through multilateral drug diplomacy. After occupying the Philippine Islands in
1898, the United States discovered Manila had 190 dens retailing a total of 130 tons of
opium. Responding to pressures from the anti-opium movement in the US, in 1903 the
colonial regime appointed the Episcopal missionary Bishop Charles Brent and two medical
doctors to an investigative opium committee that recommended total prohibition. Between
1906 and 1908, the U.S. regime banned opium smoking in the Philippines, becoming the first
American government to outlaw narcotic drugs.
The Philippine ban launched America's attempts at domestic suppression and drug diplomacy.
Aware that opium smuggling from China was sabotaging the Philippine prohibition, Bishop
Brent convinced President Theodore Roosevelt to organize the first international opium
commission. With Brent in the chair, delegations from thirteen countries met at Shanghai
for a month in 1909, passing unanimous, non-binding resolutions that urged "the
gradual suppression...of opium." Two years later, the United States used its
influence to draft The Hague Opium Convention which required each signatory nation to pass
its own domestic drug legislation. As a party to the Convention, the United States
fulfilled its diplomatic commitments in 1914 when Congress passed the Harrison Narcotics
Act, the country's first federal law restricting drug use.
In 1925, the League of Nations convened the Geneva Conference, launching a new round of
drug diplomacy, moving away from voluntary national laws to mandatory international
controls over drugs. Restrained by the colonial lobby, this cautious diplomacy produced
international treaties that gradually restricted the right of governments to traffic in
narcotics, producing an 82 percent decline in world opium supply--from 42,000 tons in 1906
to 16,000 tons in 1934. Although none of Southeast Asia's states actually abolished their
opium monopolies, all made gestures that reduced the region's opium sales by 65 percent in
the fifteen years after World War I. The Netherlands Indies, for example, cut the colony's
consumption by 88 percent, from 127 to 15 tons.
Although these reforms reduced Southeast Asia's legal opium sales, they could not
eradicate a mass demand for the drug cultivated by three centuries of colonial rule. As
soon as governments slashed imports or closed opium dens, smugglers and dealers emerged to
service the unmet demand. On the mainland, Thailand and Indochina found it impossible to
close their mountain borders to the overland caravan trade from Yunnan and Burma. With 50
percent of the region's smokers and 70 percent of its dens, Bangkok and Saigon were
Southeast Asia's premier opium markets, offering high profits which drew the caravans
southward from the opium hills.
Republican China's attempts at opium prohibition expanded both production and consumption.
After 1906, the reduction in British imports and Chinese suppression led gradually to
several negative developments: an increase in China's opium cultivation; a shift in
consumption from domestic opium to imported heroin; and a centralization of criminal
controls over the illicit opiates trade. Significantly, China's experience in the decades
before World War II demonstrated that the international opium trade had already developed
a resilience that would allow it to survive almost any attempt at suppression.
After 1909, China's early attempts at eradication created a demand for illicit morphine
and opium. As Szechwan's opium production declined, Shanghai's licensed syndicates,
notably the Green Gang, began importing morphine and heroin from Europe. Moreover, this
localized suppression in Szechwan stimulated both the spread of cultivation to other
provinces and smuggling of illicit opiates into China. Between 1911 and 1915, Japanese
traders smuggled major supplies of morphine and heroin into China. By 1923, Shanghai
syndicates were importing 10.25 tons of heroin from Japan and Europe annually to meet
consumer demand.
Starting in the late 1920s, the country's rising criminal syndicates shifted from the
import of heroin to its manufacture and distribution. On balance, the growth of the heroin
trade in northeast China was a market response to both global and local attempts at
suppression. In the decade following the League's first attempt at opiates control in
1925, Shanghai emerged as a major center for illicit heroin. During the 1930s, China began
to supply a substantial, but unquantifiable, share of the U.S. domestic drug market. In
1931, the League of Nations imposed restrictions on the manufacture of heroin in Europe,
and just three years later the U.S. Treasury attaché in Shanghai noted a "sudden
shift of the traffic in narcotics from Europe to the Orient."
When the Geneva convention banning European heroin exports took effect in 1928, Europe's
criminal entrepreneurs moved first to Istanbul, the center of a Turkish drug trade which
harvested 845 tons of opium in 1928 and manufactured 13.2 tons of heroin and morphine in
1932. Pushed by that city's violent criminal milieu and pulled by the scale of the Asian
drug trade, leading European drug dealers such as the Eliopolos brothers moved to Shanghai
and Tientsin in the early 1930s. In his 1934 report to Washington, the U.S. Treasury
attaché in Shanghai reported that there had been "an influx into China of
individuals formerly identified with the traffic in Europe." In particular, the
Jewish syndicates that dominated New York's drug trade under the leadership of Yasha
Katzenberg and Louis "Lepke" Buchalter sent agents to purchase heroin through
European dealers based in Shanghai.
Simultaneously, Shanghai's Green Gang leader Tu Yueh-sheng emerged as the city's leading
drug dealer and a key intelligence operative for the Nationalist Government--an alliance
that protected the narcotics network from the regime's anti-opium campaign of the 1930s.
By 1934, the U.S. Treasury attaché in Shanghai reported that the Green Gang leader was
the "opium King of the nation." Through his close relations with the Nationalist
regime, Tu's cartel was a major force in the Yangtze River opium trade that dominated
China's drug traffic. After the annual harvest in the southwestern highlands, according to
the US Treasury agent in Shanghai at least 18,000 tons of Szechwan and 10,000 tons of
Yunnan opium passed through the major river ports downriver to Shanghai. At the city of
Hankow, half way down Yangtze, the government's Special Tax Bureau collected $20 million
in annual opium transit fees. Indicative of Tu's control, the head of the government's
Opium Suppression Bureau, was an active member of the Green Gang who "still remains
loyal to his benefactor, Tu Yueh-sheng."
In effect, the League's attempt at global regulation and the Nationalist regime's local
suppression combined to expand China's illicit narcotics traffic. Moving beyond simple
opium growing, China had emerged as the world's main heroin manufacturer. As League
regulations barred diversion of heroin from legal laboratories to criminals, Shanghai's
Green Gang emerged as Asia's first major heroin producing syndicate in the 1930s.
b.) Causality underlying above changes:
Over the space of two centuries, China had thus progressed from opium importer to heroin exporter through the intersection of three key factors--a global commodity trade in opiates, the failure of successive interdiction campaigns, and an alliance between drug syndicates and military intelligence services.
c.) Statistics from Sources & Text for "Politics of Heroin":
1.) Increase/decrease in World Opium Production:
--World opium production declined from 41,624 tons in 1907 to an estimated 16,653 tons in 1934.
--Licit world heroin production declined from an estimated 20,000 lbs. in 1926 to only 2,200 lbs. in 1931.
2.) Changes in Opium Cultivation by Region:
--Although world total declines markedly during this period, the percentage of world production in each region within the Asian opium zone remains relatively constant.
3.) Changes in Quantity of Opium Consumption by Region:
--Between 1896 and 1924, the number of opiate addicts in the United States declines from 313,000 to an estimated 200,000.
--Although there is no indication of any decline in overall level of addiction in China, opium smoking declines and heroin use increases rapidly.
d.) Summary and Analysis of Trends within Epoch:
1.) Anti-Opium Movement: Within the Protestant churches of England and America, a moral reaction to the excesses of a market-driven expansion of drug abuse inspired a global anti-opium movement in the late 19th Century. Inspired by the larger temperance movement, the anti-opium crusade gained its force from the institutional strength of the Churches and its urgency from (1.) the influence of their China missions which felt stigmatized by the European opium trade; and, (2.) a moral revulsion against the excesses of alcohol and narcotics. Through the religious origins of the anti-opium movement, the Western, particularly American, debate over drugs becomes bound up in the metaphor of Christian warfare against evil with the parallel political goal of total extirpation.
2.) Law and Body: For the first time in the modern era, the anti-opium movement, in alliance with the larger temperance crusade, succeeded with new laws from the state restricting the individual's control over the body. Under the laissez-faire principles of 19th Century social practice, the state did nothing to restrict the individual's right to indulgence. With the passage of the Harrison Narcotics Act in 1914, the American state, for the first time, imposed the force of law over the right to use or abuse the body as the individual saw fit. This change in law constitutes a significant turning point in American social practice.
3.) Failure of Prohibition: The prewar attempt at multilateral controls over narcotics
had a mixed result. In the West, the stronger state apparatus could actively influence
social behavior and reduce drug consumption through a ban on legal sales. In the colonies
with strong, authoritarian states, such as British India, opium restrictions were even
more effective than in the West. But in Third World areas with weak states, such as China,
the attempt at prohibition produced a florescence of organized criminality.
Thus, in the 1920s, the legal opium trade, whether by states or corporations, yields to a
transnational criminal trade with powerful Chinese syndicates in Shanghai supplying
organized crime groups in the United State. With the end of alcohol prohibition in 1932,
American syndicates became even more dependent upon drug trafficking, elaborating their
transnational contacts and expanding the illicit trade.
One of the main consequences of multilateral controls was the rise of organized crime that
blunts the effectiveness of drug prohibition, forcing consumption to the social margins in
the First World and production to the spatial margins in the Third. Although repression
does reduce both production and consumption, the high profits inherent in the opiates
traffic remain to sustain criminal syndicates which now act as an unintended market
response to limit state control over the drug trade.
Despite all these considerable drawbacks, multilateral controls do have their successes.
By limiting the power of states and corporation to traffic in drugs without restriction,
the League of Nations did effect significant reductions in the gross consumption and
production of narcotics. Through these efforts, the constant, century-long upward
trajectory in drug abuse was finally broken, and, for the first time since the 18th
century, both use and production began to decline. Through these efforts, world opium
production declined from 41,600 tons in 1907 to 16,600 tons in 1934, while licit world
heroin production, much of it for recreational use, dropped sharply from an 20,000 lbs. in
1926 to only 2,200 lbs. in 1931.
Although the political parameters of the world drug trade in the prewar era were distinct,
the legacy of multilateral controls, today found in the UN Commission on Drug Abuse
Control, might well prove a viable alternative to our recent attempts at bilateral
eradication.
7.) War & Transition (1940-1947):
a.) Summary of Text in "Politics of Heroin" (pp. 113-21):
During World War II, restrictions on shipping and strict port security produced a
marked hiatus in global opium trafficking. In sum, the war cut the long-distance smuggling
routes between Asia and the West, confining the drug traffic to regional markets. Denied
illicit opiates from Asia, the United States drew limited supplies of low-grade heroin
from Mexico that failed to meet even a fraction of consumer demand. By the end of the war,
the US addict population had dropped to an historic low of some twenty thousand.
In the Middle East, Turkey and Afghanistan continued to supply the large Iranian market
without serious disruption. Similarly, China sustained its large addict population from
domestic production, with considerable assistance from the Japanese occupation forces who
were active participants in the heroin traffic. In Southeast Asia, however, local opium
monopolies were cut off from their major source in India and were forced to expand
domestic production to meet existing demand.
Despite extensive opium consumption during the colonial era, Southeast Asia had remained a
minor producer. In 1936, for example, the Shan States of Burma produced only 8 tons of raw
opium, while Laos and northern Vietnam together produced 7.5 tons in 1940. Since India
supplied their monopolies with low-cost opium, governments had no reason to encourage
local cultivation. How then do we account for the marked increase in the Golden Triangle's
opium production of 15.5 tons in 1940 to 3,050 tons in 1989?
The Golden Triangle's rise as an illicit opium producer began slowly during World War II
and then expanded rapidly in postwar decades. Cut off from sources in India and China by
the war, the French Opium Monopoly reversed its policy of suppression and encouraged poppy
cultivation among the colony's hill tribes, particularly the Hmong of Laos and Tonkin,
raising Indochina's opium production from 7.4 tons in 1940 to 60.6 tons in 1944. This 800
percent increase in the local harvest was sufficient to maintain supplies for the colony's
100,000 plus addicts and allow a rise in drug revenues from 15 to 24 million piasters.
During the war, moreover, Thailand annexed the Shan States of northeastern Burma and used
its military occupation to supply Bangkok's monopoly with smoking opium. In May 1942, the
Thai Northern Army marched into the Shan market town at Kengtung where Major General Phin
Choonhawan, governor of what Bangkok now called the "United Thai State,"
established a military administration.
A few months later, the Thai Opium Monopoly imported 36 tons from the Shan States, raising
opium revenues to a record level. At war's end, when Japanese forces began to suffer
reverses on the Indian front, Bangkok ordered Governor Phin home from Kengtung and
demobilized his Northern Army. Although this operation was a minor footnote to the war's
main battles, some of the political links that would later bind these disparate highlands
into the Golden Triangle opium zone were forged during the Thai occupation. Significantly,
after World War II many of the key Thai military who dominated the country's politics and
controlled the opium traffic with Burma were veterans of Shan State occupation.
b.) Statistics from Text & Sources for "Politics of Heroin":
1.) Increase/decrease in World Opium Production:
--There is no accurate data of any description on world opium production for this period.
2.) Changes in Opium Cultivation by Region:
--In Burma, opium production increased from 8 tons in 1936 to an approximate 36 tons in 1942.
--In French Indochina (Laos and North Vietnam), opium production increased from 7.4 tons in 1940 to 60.6 tons in 1944.
--Mexico experienced some increase in opium production in response to demand from the United States.
3.) Changes in Quantity of Opium Consumption by Region:
--In the United States, the number of heroin addicts decreased from an estimated 200,000 in 1924 to just 20,000 in 1944-45.
c.) Summary and Analysis of Trends within Epoch:
Developments in the drug trade during World War II show, as China would after the war,
that perfect coercion can have an influence, direct and dramatic, on the international
heroin trade. Massive wartime security over ports, impossible in peacetime, meant an end
of drug smuggling to the United States.
By implication, less than perfect coercion will little impact on the global narcotics
traffic and will, under most circumstances, produce minor seizures that will serve as a
surcharge that will be passed on to consumers.
8.) Cold War Opium Expansion (1948-1972):
a.) Summary of Text in "Politics of Heroin"( pp. 121-30, 269-82):
The forty years of the Cold War brought major changes to the world's illicit opium
traffic. The Communist victory in China eliminated the world's major opium market within a
decade, and simultaneously forced remnants of the old Nationalist regime into margins of
Southeast Asia where they played a catalytic role in expanding that region's drug traffic.
Although the Asian opium zone contracted geographically, Cold War geo-politics, combined
with illicit market forces, stimulated a steady increase in opium production in the
remaining area, which now stretched from Turkey to Thailand.
Supplied by the Asian zone, other markets expanded their consumption of opiates steadily
during this period. With morphine base from Turkey, the Corsican syndicate laboratories of
Marseilles, the so-called "French connection," processed an estimated 80 percent
of the high-grade No. 4 heroin consumed in the US from 1948 to 1973, nearly a quarter
century. Similarly, Turkey and Afghanistan produced smoking opium for the near insatiable
demand among the million plus opium smokers of Iran, which became, after the Chinese
revolution, the world's leading opium consumer.
After 1949, the Chinese Communist regime used a mix of unrestrained repression and social
reform to eradicate the world's largest opium market. By the mid 1950s, highland opium
areas had converted to new crops, dealers had been executed, and the country's estimated
10 million addicts has been forced into compulsory treatment.
The collapse of the Nationalist Chinese regime in 1949 forced its remnants into the drug
markets of Hong Kong and Southeast Asia where they soon played a catalytic role in an
expansion of opium production. In 1949, Shanghai's narcotics syndicate fled to Hong Kong
where they soon opened heroin refineries. Suffering reverses in a struggle for control of
the colony's heroin trade against local syndicates, Green Gang faded by the mid 1950s and
was replaced by small syndicates of ethnic Chiu Chau criminals who traced their origins to
nearby Swatow on China's south coast. Using the Green Gang's chemists, these new narcotic
networks expanded the colony's heroin consumption during the 1950s and then extended their
operations into Southeast Asia in the 1960s. Significantly, Hong Kong syndicate chemists
opened the first No. 4 heroin laboratories along the Thai-Burma border in the late 1960s,
introducing the technology that made the Golden Triangle the world's largest heroin
producer.
Through an accident of history, the southern borders of China and the Soviet Union, a
major fault line of Cold War confrontation, happened to parallel the Asian opium zone.
Since the 18th Century, opium has been cultivated as a cash crop in a highland zone that
extends for 5,000 miles across the southern rim of Asia from Turkey to Thailand. During
the forty years of the Cold War, the coincidence super power confrontation and opium
cultivation made geo-political pressures a real force in shaping the political economy of
this zone.
As various national intelligence agencies mounted special operations along the Asian zone,
they found that the region's opium brokers and ethnic warlords were their most effective
covert-action assets. Surveying the steady increase in world opium production since the
end of World War II, we can thus discern periodic surges in opium supply that coincide
with ethnic conflicts or special operations in the drug zones.
The sudden growth of Golden Triangle opium production in the 1950s appears, in retrospect,
a response to two stimuli. Reacting to international pressures, governments abolished
legal opium sales and thereby created a sudden demand for illicit opiates in the Southeast
Asia's cities. Moreover, an informal alliance among four intelligence services--Thai,
American, French and Nationalist Chinese--played a catalytic role in promoting the
production of opium in northern Laos and the Shan Plateau of northern Burma. In
particular, the Nationalist Chinese (Kuomintang, or KMT) occupation in 1950, combined with
the Shan secessionist revolt after 1958, transformed the Shan States into a region of
conflict that reduced government control and allowed a marked expansion in local opium
production.
During the First Indochina War (1947-54), French intelligence officers integrated their
covert warfare with the Golden Triangle opium trade through a motivation that seems, on
its face, simple. Denied funds by National Assembly, French intelligence merged the opium
supply of Laos with the drug demand of Saigon to fund covert operations against Vietnam's
communists. After the French colonial regime abolished the Opium Monopoly in 1950,
military intelligence took control of the drug trade. French paratroopers fighting with
Hmong guerrillas in Laos and Tonkin shipped their clients' opium south to Saigon on French
military aircraft where it was sold in smoking dens run by the Binh Xuyen bandits, a
criminal syndicate that controlled the city. Through this operation, French intelligence,
particularly the SDECE, integrated narcotics into Indochina's political economy and its
anti-communist political forces.
Across the Mekong in Burma and Thailand, an alliance of intelligence services--Taiwan,
Thailand, and US--fought a purer kind of covert warfare by operating indirectly through
their local clients. Controlling the opium hills of northeastern Burma, Nationalist
Chinese irregulars supplied the demand for drugs in Bangkok. To provide logistic support
for their forces, the Nationalists forged a tactical alliance with Thailand's dominant
military leader, Police General Phao Sriyanonda, that soon evolved into a de facto
division of the Burma-to-Bangkok opium trade.
Initially, the Nationalist Chinese forces invaded Yunnan Province in southwest China,
seeking to inspire a mass uprising against the new Communist regime. After at least three
failed invasions of Yunnan with heavy losses of men and equipment in 1951-1952, the KMT
forces fell back into Burma's prime opium lands between the Salween River and the China
border--7,300 troops in the Wa States and 4,400 further south in Kengtung State. As allied
aid gradually declined, the Chinese KMT irregulars turned to opium trading to finance
their operations. Forcing local hill tribes to produce opium through a mix of coercion and
market incentives, the Nationalist troops presided over a massive increase of poppy
cultivation on the Shan Plateau and sent opium caravans south into Thailand to supply the
region's growing illicit markets.
After a joint Burma-China military operation evicted them from the Shan States in 1961,
the KMT forces established new base camps just across the border in Thailand and from
there dominated the Shan States opium trade until the early 1980s. During their
decade-long occupation of Burma's prime opium lands between the Salween River and the
Chinese border, the KMT fostered a generation of local opium warlords such as Olive Yang,
Lo Hsing-han, and Khun Sa who remained in Burma after the KMT departure to struggle, as
both antagonists and allies, for control of the local traffic. By the mid 1960s, the high
profits of the Shan opium trade financed the formation of new armies, notably Khun Sa's
Shan United Army (SUA), that would challenge Nationalist Chinese dominion and expropriate
much of the traffic by the late 1970s. Even after the KMT's control faded, opium continued
to dominate the region's economy, corrupting all contenders for control of Burma's
northeast--Shan rebels, Chinese warlords, the Communist Party of Burma, and Rangoon's
military regime.
By the mid-1960s, Southeast Asia had a self-contained narcotics industry producing enough
raw opium to sustain addicts in the region's cities. Following a pattern seen elsewhere,
local demand raised the region's opium harvest to levels sufficient for an eventual entry
into the world market, and then sustained it during periodic downturns in global demand.
Although Hong Kong's chemists had been producing heroin from Southeast Asian opium since
the mid 1950s, heroin laboratories did not open in the Golden Triangle until the US
military presence in South Vietnam created a local demand for No. 4 heroin. In 1968-1969,
Hong Kong syndicate chemists opened a cluster of heroin laboratories at the epicenter of
the Golden Triangle. Controlled by the Nationalist Chinese generals in Thailand and the
Commander of the Royal Lao Army, these laboratories produced substantial quantities of 90
percent pure heroin.
Fueled by these nearly limitless supplies, heroin use among US troops in South Vietnam
reached epidemic proportions. In September 1970, Army medical officers questioned 3,103
soldiers of the Americal Division and found that 11.9 percent had used heroin since their
arrival in Vietnam. In November, an Army Engineers battalion in the Mekong Delta reported
that 14 percent of its troops were regular heroin users. In 1972, the White House Office
for Drug Abuse Prevention interviewed 900 enlisted men who had returned from Vietnam in
September 1971, the peak of the epidemic, and found that 44 percent had tried opiates
while in Vietnam and 20 percent regarded themselves as having been "addicted."
The full extent of the problem was not revealed until 1974 when the Office for Drug Abuse
Prevention published later surveys showing that 34 percent of US troops in Vietnam had
"commonly used" heroin. Assuming this figure to be correct, then by mid 1971
there were more American heroin users in South Vietnam (81,300) than there were in the
entire United States (68,000).
The causes underlying the GI drug epidemic were complex. In retrospect, however, boredom
and bad morale provided much of the motivation. Under President Nixon's Vietnamization
program launched in 1969, US troops were confined to cantonments as a strategic reserve
for ARVN, and most units, without a clear mission, suffered a sharp decline in morale.
With days stretching into months without event or ending, soldiers apparently took heroin
to dull the psychological pain and accelerate the 365-day clock that marked the maximum
tour of each soldier. Not surprisingly, the accelerated withdrawal of U.S. combat forces
in 1971-1972 forced Southeast Asian syndicates to seek new markets for their heroin
production.
b.) Statistics from Text & Sources for "Politics of Heroin":
1.) Increase/decrease in World Opium Production:
--World opium production dropped dramatically from an estimated 16,653 tons in 1934 to only 1,094 tons in 1970.
2.) Changes in Opium Cultivation by Region:
--During the 1950s, all opium production in China was eradicated, eliminating the producer of 85 percent of total world production in 1906-07.
--For the first time, Southeast Asia's Golden Triangle region becomes a significant opium producer--increasing from 15.5 tons in 1940, to 97 tons in 1944, to 713 tons in 1970. By 1970, the Golden Triangle accounts for 67 percent of world illicit opium supply.
--In Burma, opium production rose from 8 tons in 1936 to 500 tons in 1970.
--In Southwest Asia (Iran, Afghanistan, India, Turkey) opium production dropped from 1,126 tons in 1934 to 381 tons in 1970.
--Rising from low, unknown levels, Mexican opium production reached 15 tons in 1970.
3.) Changes in Quantity of Opium Consumption by Region:
--The US addict population rose from 20,000 in 1945, to 68,000 in 1969, to an estimated
559,000 in 1973.
c.) Summary and Analysis of Trends within Epoch:
1.) Production Areas: External intervention in the remote tribal areas along the Asian opium zone contributed to the rise of drug lords and their armies, allowing them to position themselves for a massive expansion of local opium production. By providing arms, logistics, organization, and political protection, external alliances created the preconditions for a later leap in opium production in Burma and Afghanistan.
2.) Chinese Eradication: During the Cold War era, the most dramatic change was the
sudden and complete eradication of opium in China. Under a powerful communist state,
perfect prohibition works and produces a major change in the opium trade, eliminating the
source of some 85 percent of prewar world supply.
This extraordinary event has, however, no real lesson for capitalist democracies
struggling with the problem of drug abuse. To extract some tenuous policy prescription
from the Chinese Revolution would serve to trivialize a major historical event.
9.) Origins of US Bilateral Suppression (1973-1979):
a.) Summary of Text in "Politics of Heroin":
As American troops were withdrawing from Vietnam in 1972, President Richard Nixon
inadvertently created a new market for Southeast Asian heroin by declaring a "war on
drugs" in the Mediterranean. As the progenitor of the three drug wars the US has
fought over the past 20 years, Nixon's effort commands close attention. Despite a
short-term "victory," there were two long-term consequences of this drug war:
(1.) increased global opium production; and, (2.) rising heroin consumption.
Acting on reports that Turkey's poppy fields and France's laboratories supplied 80 percent
of America's heroin, Nixon pressed these two allies to eliminate the drug trade. By 1973,
Turkey, supported by $35.7 million in U.S. aid, had eradicated all opium production and
the French government had closed most of the heroin laboratories in the Marseilles region.
Within months, the street price of heroin in New York had tripled and purity dropped by
half--both indicators of a serious shortage. Indeed, the DEA estimated that the U.S.
addict population dropped from some 500,000 in 1974-1975 to only 200,000 by the end of the
decade. Clearly, President Nixon had scored a major victory in his "war on
drugs."
Ironically, President Nixon's victory in Turkey increased global drug demand, unleashing
market forces that would ultimately expand both production and consumption of illicit
narcotics. The Nixon drug war rested on the premise that Turkey was an isolated opium
producer that could be eliminated through a strong enforcement effort. Turkey, in 1970,
had produced just 7 percent of the world's illicit supply. It was, moreover, the western
extremity of a near continuous opium zone that stretched for 5,000 miles along the
mountain rim of Asia--through Iran, Afghanistan, Pakistan, Burma, Thailand, and Laos.
Although U.S. officials seemed to view this broad zone as a series of self-contained
sectors (Middle East, South West Asia, and Southeast Asia), this functional economic
region responded to stimuli from the global drug market with a simultaneity that seems to
indicate economic coherence. Any reduction of production in a single sector, such as
Turkey, soon became a strong market stimulus for increased production elsewhere along the
opium zone.
Reacting to the decline in heroin shipments from the Mediterranean, the Chinese syndicates
of Southeast Asia began exporting their surplus heroin to America, in effect following the
GIs home. Rising from insignificant levels in the late 1960s, Southeast Asian heroin
captured 29 percent of New York's street supply by 1972. In Chicago, Southeast Asia's
share jumped from 6 percent of all samples seized in 1972 to 48 percent in 1973. A wave of
arrests of Chinese merchant seamen jumping ship on the East Coast in 1972 signaled an
upsurge of Asian heroin smuggling. During the early 1970s, Southeast Asia's share of the
overall U.S. heroin market reached an estimated 26 to 30 percent of total street supply.
Concerned about rising Southeast Asian heroin seizures, the Nixon administration
dispatched a "fire-break team" of 30 Drug Enforcement Administration (DEA)
agents to Bangkok in 1973-1974 to cut the flow. Armed with a financial war chest that
included $12 million in narcotics assistance funds, the Bangkok DEA seconded a branch of
the Thai police to its service and soon began making substantial seizures of US-bound
heroin. By 1976, Southeast Asian heroin dropped from a peak of 30 percent to about 8
percent of the total seized on the streets of American cities. Moreover, the DEA presence
contributed to the elimination of several leading exporters of Southeast Asia opiates. In
1973, the Marcos regime executed a Manila heroin manufacturer, Lim Seng, who was exporting
major quantities to the United States. In 1974, Hong Kong Police broke the Ng Sik-ho
syndicate, disrupting the colony's export operations. As Southeast Asian exports dropped,
Mexico's share of the US market jumped from 40 percent in 1972 to 90 percent in 1975.
Since the DEA did not eradicate opium cultivation on the Shan Plateau or close the heroin
refineries in northern Thailand, its seizures simply erected a de-facto Custom's shield
that deflected exports from the United States to other markets. If the region's loosely
structured opium industry were instead a legal corporation, then the import duties it was
required to pay for access to key markets were, in effect, becoming prohibitive. Barred
from the prime US drug market, Southeast Asia's syndicates were forced to find new markets
or go out of business. There are, of course, only four First World regions capable of
sustaining the high costs of the transnational heroin trade--America, Japan, Europe and
Australia.
Denied access to the United States by DEA operations and barred from Japan by an entente
between the state and syndicates that discouraged narcotics, Southeast Asian syndicates
began exporting heroin to Europe and Australia. During the 1970s, police statistics from
both continents indicated a parallel surge in illicit heroin use. Total European seizures
of Southeast Asian No. 3 heroin jumped from 22 pounds in 1972 to 873 in 1978. By 1976,
European seizures of 1,177 pounds of heroin, almost all from Southeast Asia, were higher
than the U.S. total for all source countries. Indicative of Europe's rising addiction
rates, the Netherlands' addict population increased from 100 in 1970 to 10,000 by 1975. In
West Germany, deaths from heroin overdose increased from 9 in 1969 to 623 a decade later.
By the end of the decade, Europe was, for the first time in its history, consuming more
heroin than the United States. Similarly, in Australia narcotics arrests in the state of
New South Wales increased five-fold from 173 in 1972 to 909 in 1977; while over-dose
deaths were up three-fold from 14 in 1974 to 49 in 1976.
Although Nixon's drug war thus stimulated the global market, its impact on US domestic
supply was more ambiguous. In the late 1970s every indicator--addiction, purity, and
price--pointed to a decline in America's heroin supply. Why? Did Nixon's drug war succeed
in slowing the flow of drugs into the United States?
Mexico had captured nearly 90 percent of the US heroin market, but its granular No. 3
heroin failed to satisfy American demand for the No. 4 powder processed in Europe and
Southeast Asia. In the mid 1970s, as Turkish supplies dwindled and Southeast Asia failed
to fill the void, Mexico's production boomed and its Sierra Madre became America's major
source of heroin. Although Mexican opium cultivation had been extremely low and supplied a
tiny slice of the U.S. heroin market in the 1950s, a quarter century later Mexico's
expanded poppy cultivation supplied almost the entire US market.
Mexico's dominance of the U.S. supply with low-grade No. 3 heroin coincided with a marked
decline in U.S. heroin demand during the mid-1970s, providing some hope that this
bilateral approach might have been effective. As U.S. enforcement efforts took effect and
the drug flow from Mexico began to slow in the late 1970s, unmet U.S. demand for drugs
stimulated renewed Southeast Asian exports that briefly captured about one-third of the
American market. Even so, supplies of heroin from all sources were still limited, and US
consumption, by all indicators, remained low.
Looking at these changes, we could conclude that Nixon's drug war had actually worked.
Examining other evidence, however, we could attribute this decline to President Carter's
foreign policy. His cessation of covert operations from 1976 to 1978 may have removed,
albeit inadvertently, the protection that drug lords seem to require. Similarly, Carter's
abandonment of the Nixon "drug war" strategy might have stalled the bilateral
operations that had in the past stimulated production. Complicating the situation further,
Southeast Asia, the world's major opium producer, suffered a major drought in 1978 to 1980
that slashed its opium production by more than 75 percent.
Given the complexities of the global drug trade, we cannot decide this issue with absolute
certainty. Whatever the complex causality underlying the decline in US heroin consumption
in the late 1970s might have been, a close review of the global traffic indicates that
prohibition and protection were, on balance, the operative factors in a sudden revival of
heroin abuse during the 1980s.
b.) Causality underlying above changes:
When President Nixon launched America's first drug war in Asia and brought the blunt
baton of law enforcement down on a global commodity, heroin, the results were mixed.
Although repression disrupted the global heroin trade for several years, over the longer
term Nixon's drug war stimulated both global opium production and heroin consumption.
Ignoring these lessons, the Reagan and Bush administrations later pursued parallel
policies in Latin America with dismal results. In essence, all three drug wars extended a
local law enforcement model into the international arena in a way that failed to reduce
either drug production or exports.
Like heroin before it, cocaine grew during the 1980s into a major commodity that was
fully, albeit invisibly, integrated into legitimate inter-American economic relations.
Despite Washington's drug wars, U.S. consumption fueled an increase in coca cultivation--
rising in Bolivia from 4,800 metric tons in 1963 to some 56,400 to 155,452 tons in 1988.
Stimulated in part by three US drug wars, Asian opium production enjoyed a parallel
increase from 1,094 tons in 1970 to 4,016 tons in 1989.
How can we explain the failure of a major US foreign policy initiative? It appears that
the policy of repression is based on a misperception of the nature of the global narcotics
traffic. White House policy has ignored the market dynamics of the global drug trade.
Since the late 18th century, narcotics have emerged as a major commodity with Third World
producers and First World consumers linked in an elaborate exchange. The initial
prohibition of narcotics during the 1920s did not eradicate the trade, but simply drove it
into an illicit economy controlled by upland drug lords and urban crime syndicates.
When law enforcement is applied to such an elaborate commerce, drug syndicates usually
react in ways not foreseen by enforcement agencies. Treating the global narcotics traffic
as if it were a localized vice such as pornography or prostitution, U.S. drug agencies
often apply repression without any awareness of the intricate dynamics of these worldwide
marketing systems. For both legal and illicit commodities, a crop failure in one
production zone--whether from war, drought, or disease--creates a shortage of supply and
raises the price for producers elsewhere, stimulating increased production in the next
crop cycle.
c.) Statistics from Sources & Text for "Politics of Heroin":
1.) Increase/decrease in World Opium Production:
--World opium production increased steadily from in 1,094 tons in 1970 to 1,450 tons in 1981.
2.) Changes in Opium Cultivation by Region:
--Turkish illicit opium production declined radically from 58 tons in 1971 to zero by 1974-75.
--In Southwest Asia (Iran, Afghanistan, Pakistan), opium production rose from 504 tons in 1971 to an estimated 1,400 tons in 1978.
--In Southeast Asia's Golden Triangle, drought cut opium production from 700 tons in 1971 to only 160 tons in 1979.
--Mexican opium production remains relatively constant at 16 tons in both 1971 and 1981.
3.) Changes in Quantity of Opium Consumption by Region:
--In the United States, estimated number of heroin addicts declined sharply from an estimated 500,000 in 1971 to 200,000 in 1979.
--Rising from low levels in 1970, Western Europe had an estimated 190,000 to 330,000 heroin addicts in 1979-80.
--In the Netherlands, estimated number of heroin addicts grew from 100 in 1970 to 10,000 in 1975.
--In West Germany, heroin overdose deaths increased from 9 in 1969 to 623 in 1979.
d.) Summary and Analysis of Trends within Epoch:
1.) Bilateral Suppression & Crime: During the mid 1970s, the US attempt at bilateral suppression of opiates (a.) expanded international criminal networks; (b.) increased global opium production; and (c.) encourages a spread of heroin consumption to new regions of the globe.
2.) Limits of Bilateral Suppression: Although bilateral operations in Turkey during the
mid 1970s represent the greatest success of any US "drug war," the policy
implications are limited. In retrospect, Turkey's suppression worked because, like Iran or
British India before World War II, the government licensed and controlled opium
cultivation. Moreover, the opium farmers were ethnic Turks, the majority population,
working at the epicenter of the nation-state, not an alienated ethnic minority, armed and
insurgent. This combination of a strong state and weak local resistance made this exercise
in bilateral suppression effective.
These conditions are not, however, likely to be replicated anywhere else in the world.
Similarly, the strong French state could eliminate the Corsican laboratories in Marseilles
when US pressure was insistent. Elsewhere--in Burma, Afghanistan, or Pakistan--the state
is weak and ethnic resistance to opium eradication is strong, making future bilateral
operations in these critical areas problematic.
10.) Production Increase in Asian Zone (1979-1989):
a.) Summary of Text in "Politics of Heroin":
After a decline in US drug use from the mid-1970s to the mid-1980s, a complex of
factors encouraged a steady recovery in America's demand for heroin. During the 1980s,
global production and consumption of the drug increased steadily, laying the foundation
for a sudden surge in supply during next decade that would make heroin a "world
drug" by the early 1990s.
During the 1980s, a complex factors led to an increase in Asian opium production. Unusual
weather patterns led to a failure in the monsoon rains, bringing a two-year drought that
slashed the Golden Triangle's opium production drastically to some 165 tons in 1979 and
225 tons in 1980. Responding to the market opportunity, heroin production in South West
Asia--Afghanistan and Pakistan--suddenly expanded to fill gaps in the global market. By
1979, South West Asian heroin had captured the European market. As Dutch seizures of
Southeast Asian heroin dropped from 193 pounds in 1979 to 6.5 in 1980, so European
seizures of South West Asian heroin jumped from 911 pounds to 1,980 in the same period.
From insignificant levels of heroin use in 1970, Western Europe had developed an addict
population estimated at 190,000 to 330,000 users by the end of the decade--a heroin market
larger than America's.
In 1980-1981, heroin from South West Asia also fueled a new surge of use in the United
States. After a quarter-century of rising heroin addiction, America had enjoyed a brief
respite during the late-1970s. U.S. diplomacy in Turkey and DEA interdiction in Bangkok
had slowed Asia's drug exports, allowing America its first prolonged heroin drought since
World War II. By late 1980, however, the flood of heroin from Pakistan and Afghanistan
captured 60 percent of the US market and brought a renewed heroin crisis. As
heroin-related injuries climbed 25 percent during the year, the US addict population
climbed back to 450,000. With an estimated production of 1,600 tons, South West Asia's
opium crop was three times larger than the 450 tons that the Golden Triangle had produced
in its last good year, 1977-1978.
There were signs that the situation would worsen. Without any restraint on production or
processing, heroin exports from Pakistan and Afghanistan continued to grow. Rising from
about 100 tons in 1971, Afghanistan's opium production reached 300 tons in 1982 and then
doubled to 575 tons in the next harvest. Recovering from a two-year failure of the monsoon
rains, Southeast Asia's Golden Triangle produced a bumper opium crop in 1981 that would,
in the words of the U.S. Attorney-General, "provide enough heroin to glut the world
market." Other illicit drug sales were also rising. Between 1979 and 1980 alone,
street sales of all illicit drugs in the United States increased by 22 percent to $79
billion. While America's heroin imports rose by 7 percent to four tons worth about $8
billion, cocaine supply jumped a remarkable 57 percent to 44 tons worth $29 billion.
Despite some initial success, America's drug war had thus produced a paradoxical
strengthening of the global narcotics traffic. By the late 1970s, the simplex of the
Turkey-Marseilles-New York heroin pipeline had been replaced by a complex of international
smuggling routes that tied the disparate zones of First World consumption to Third World
narcotics production. With production and consumption now dispersed about the globe, the
international traffic was far more resistant to suppression than ever before.
Changes in Italy's heroin market during the 1970s are one example of the negative impact
of the US "drug war." In effect, the Nixon initiative propelled the mafia to a
new plateau of development. After US diplomatic pressure forced French police to close
Marseilles' heroin laboratories in 1973-74, the Corsican syndicates moved their refining
operations across the border into Italy in alliance with the mafia. When the Afghan War
started in 1979, moreover, the mafia's role in the Atlantic heroin trade reached an
unprecedented peak. By 1981, Pakistani laboratories, with the Sicilian mafia as their
intermediaries, were supplying over 60 percent of the US heroin demand and an even greater
proportion of Europe's market. By the mid-1980s, an individual mafia cosce, the
Badalmenti, was distributing bulk heroin directly across America through the facade of
local pizza parlors and accumulating extraordinarily profits. As seen in "Operation
Green Ice" of 1987-88, the Madonia family of Palermo allied with the Medellin cartel
to import 596 kilograms of cocaine from Colombia for distribution in Europe. In effect,
during the 1980s, the mafia had emerged as the prime narcotics broker between Asia,
Europe, and the Americas--exporting Asian heroin to North America and importing Latin
American cocaine for distribution across Europe.
The influx of heroin profits into Sicily during the 1970s and 1980s expanded the mafia's
political power. The sudden wave of high-rise construction in corridors beyond Palermo's
central city were financed largely by mafia factions laundering their drug profits,
allowing major families to increase their local power. While the modern mafia may have
grown Mercury's wings to move drugs across Asia to the Americas, the logic of laundering
brought its cosce back home to Palermo to seek a safe haven for narco profits. Such an
expanded local base may also have contributed to mafia's growing penetration of the
Italian state. With a vast capital from its role as heroin broker, the mafia increased its
control over the hidden politics that operated at the intersection of the Italian state,
parties, corporations and criminality. Specifically, the better capitalized mafia cosce
were able to begin dictating the agenda for public works and the allocation of their
illegal profits, reaching beyond the South to the whole of Italy.
Heroin trafficking also had negative consequences for the mafia. In the 1980s, Europe
emerged as the world's second major drug market, with an explosive growth and
unprecedented profits. Between 1982 and 1991, Europe's seizures of heroin increased from
1,355 kilograms to 6,770, while its cocaine seizures jumped from 396 kilograms to 13,773.
As heroin leached from the mafia's international routes into local traffic, the number of
Italian addicts grew sharply. Between 1977 and 1982, heroin overdose deaths in Italy rose
from 40 to 252--a clear indication of a rapidly expanding drug problem. As heroin became a
Italian affliction, the mafia's involvement in trafficking contributed to a de facto
delegitimation, redoubling public and official opposition.
Paralleling these changes in Italy, by the early 1980s the global opiates market had
survived the reverses of the previous decade, emerging with the capacity for explosive
growth. In part through U.S. interdiction efforts in the 1970s, narcotics consumption had
spread to new continents and global production had expanded, rendering the illicit drug
trade far more resistant to suppression.
The Reagan-Bush drug wars of the 1980s provide further evidence of the counterproductive
impact of U.S. efforts at supply-side suppression. During the 1980s, America experienced
an unprecedented drug crisis. Between 1982 and 1985, U.S. cocaine consumption more than
doubled to 72 tons. As supplies grew and prices dropped between 1981 and 1986, the number
of Americans using cocaine rose by 38 percent to 5.8 million. Responding to public panic
over cocaine, the Reagan and Bush administrations deployed an escalating repression that
drew the military into their drug wars.
By early 1991, the Bush White House, citing survey results showing a decline in cocaine
abuse, claimed a near-victory in its war on drugs. A closer look at long term trends
indicated, however, that the illicit drug trade had again reacted to repression by
adjusting in unexpected ways. When Bush's campaign reduced the cachet and quantity of
illicit cocaine, the drug market filled the void with a "new" heroin that
appealed to both lower-class crack addicts and middle-class cocaine users.
As the war on cocaine escalated in the 1980s, there were signs that the era of
experimentation and casual soft drug use was, after twenty years, coming to a close. While
casual use faded, the numbers of regular, or "hard core," cocaine and heroin
users "remained high." As Dr. James Van Wert noted in mid 1991,
"cocaine-related deaths have increased by 10 percent since 1988, daily cocaine users
increased by 15 percent." Moreover, there were indications of an overlapping demand
for either heroin or cocaine in America's illicit drug culture. Although some local
markets showed a preference for a particular drug, such as Miami for cocaine or New York
for heroin, there was a growing tendency across the country for regular drug users to take
both. Between 1981 and 1985, for example, deaths from "speedballs," a mixture of
cocaine and heroin, rose by 754 percent.
Eclipsed by media focus on cocaine and crack, global heroin production and U.S.
consumption rose steadily during the 1980s. World opium production tripled from an
estimated 1,500 tons in 1982 to 4,100 in 1989. The U.S. population of heroin addicts had
stabilized at about 500,000 in the early 1980s, but there were subsequent signs of rising
use. Between 1983 and 1986, the number of heroin-related deaths doubled. Moreover, a new
Mexican "black tar" heroin appeared in the mid 1980s with a high purity and low
price that made it competitive with crack in the western United States.
While supplies from Mexico and South West Asia waxed and waned, the Golden Triangle
increased its share of the US heroin market from 18 percent in 1987 to 45 percent in 1990.
As the long drought in the Golden Triangle ended in 1980, farm-gate opium prices in Burma
soared from $91 in January 1979 to $399 the following June, boosting production from a low
of 160 tons in 1979 to 2,528 tons in 1989. Thus, between 1984 and 1990, Southeast Asia's
share of the New York City heroin supply jumped from 5 to 80 percent. Following this
significant local trend, in 1993-94, Southeast Asia supplied an estimated 80 percent of
the total US market for heroin. Then, in 1989-1990, a flood of Southeast Asian heroin
lowered the wholesale price of "China white" in New York from $100,000 a
kilogram to only $60,000, undercutting the cocaine market and creating a new clientele for
the drug. Crack addicts seeking an easier withdrawal were reportedly using heroin in large
quantities, as were those mixing the two drugs for a more prolonged euphoria. "The
heroin situation is growing on a daily basis," reported the DEA's heroin specialist
in mid 1990. "There's big profits, and the production of opium has doubled...It is
the tip of the iceberg."
Although White House drug policy treated cocaine and heroin as discreet drug markets,
there was in fact an overlapping demand for both narcotics. Within America's polydrug
culture, Asian heroin could and did supply a shortfall in demand for Latin American
cocaine.
b.) Statistics from Sources & Text for "Politics of Heroin":
1.) Increase/decrease in World Opium Production:
--During this single decade, world opium production tripled from 1,450 tons in 1981 to a postwar peak of 4,105 tons in 1989.
2.) Changes in Opium Cultivation by Region:
--South West Asia (Iran, Afghanistan, Pakistan) increased its opium production from 800 tons in 1981, to 1,060 in 1989, remaining the world' leading producer until 1986 when it was passed by Southeast Asia.
--Production in Southeast Asia's Golden Triangle rose sharply from 650 tons in 1981 to 2,956 tons in 1989, becoming the source of 72 percent of world opium supply.
--In Burma, opium production grew from 550 tons in 1981 to 2,528 in 1989, making this single country the source of 62 percent of world opium supply.
--Under its new communist regime, Laos increases its opium production from 50 tons in 1981 to 378 tons in 1989.
--In Mexico opium production shot from 16 tons in 1982 to 76 tons in 1989.
3.) Changes in Quantity of Opium Consumption by Region:
--US addict population increased from 200,000 in the late 1970s to 450,000 in 1982.
c.) Summary and Analysis of Trends within Epoch:
1.) Rise of the Drug Lords: During this period, highland drug lords, for the first time
in the history of the traffic, began to act as independent entrepreneurs, responding
creatively to market opportunities and taking significant initiatives to expand production
and markets for their product. In Burma, for example, opium production increased
exponentially from 550 tons in 1981 to 2,500 in 1989, in large part through the efforts of
leading warlords like Khun Sa who controlled some 75 percent of the country's heroin
production by the late 1980s. Although there, of course numerous underlying ecological and
economic factors, Khun Sa's centralization of control over the Shan revolt and his
determination to expand heroin production had a significant impact on the global traffic
and the US drug problem.
Similarly, the emergence of Gulbuddin Hekmatyar as the dominant rebel leader in
Afghanistan created a parallel figure of power who could control much of the country's
opium production, heroin processing, and export.
The capacity of powerful warlords such as these to both produce and export has had a
growing influence on Western heroin markets--sending vast new supplies of Burmese heroin
to America and giving the Sicilian mafia a major new role as brokers for South West Asian
heroin to Europe and the United States.
2.) Failure of Tolerance: While bilateral attempts at suppression may compound the problem beyond the target nation, extreme tolerance or simple inaction over drugs within a producing nation had led to an explosive growth in opium cultivation. After 1984-85, the Burmese government capitulated to the drug lords and Khun Sa formed a powerful new opium army--a combination that led to a surge in the country's opium production from 550 tons in 1981 to 2,500 in 1989. Similarly, Afghanistan, the collapse over government control over the countryside since the early 1980s is another apt case of the same proposition. The lesson: if a government abandons any attempt at suppression in its opium areas, the capacity for increased production is restrained only by land and labor.
3.) Failure of Drug Wars: If the United States is to purse a strategy of international repression, then focusing on a single drug seems a prescription for long-term failure. By focusing on cocaine in Colombia and, in effect, ignoring heroin in Burma, the United States allowed Burma's opium production to grow without restraint, creating an ample supply of an alternative narcotic for the US market.
11.) Global Proliferation of Opium (1989-1994):
a.) Summary of Text in "Politics of Heroin":
In the early 1990s, heroin recovered its historic preeminence as a leading illicit
narcotic and became something of a "world" drug. After 1989, Southeast Asia
began a sustained heroin export drive to the US that captured over 80 percent of our
market by 1993. Simultaneously, the end of Afghan war and repatriation of refugees led to
expanded local heroin production. Increasing Central Asia's potential for opium
cultivation, the break-up of Soviet Union led to independence for its former Central Asian
Republics and, through ethnic links with Afghanistan, an extension of poppy farming into
Tajikistan and Uzbekistan. Facilitating the export of Central Asian heroin, the rise of
new criminal syndicates in Eastern Europe and Russia, in alliance with Colombian cartels
and Sicilian mafia, is creating new smuggling routes that lead from Afghanistan across
Russia to the West. Driven by the unequaled profitability of heroin, the Cali cartel has
introduced opium cultivation to the northern slopes of the Andes, harvesting some 20 tons
annually since 1991.
Increased opium supply has led to a dramatic proliferation of heroin abuse around the
globe--a phenomenon so vast that we can speak, without hyperbole, of a
"globalization" of heroin consumption. Paralleling the rise of use in
established consuming regions like Western Europe and North America, heroin abuse shot
upward in new areas--Eastern Europe, southern China, mainland Southeast Asia, India, and
Pakistan. Rising from a situation of zero heroin addicts in 1979, Pakistan had, according
to official statistics, 5,000 addicts in 1980, 1.2 million in 1985, and 1.7 million in
1993.
As cheaper grades of heroin have encouraged mass addiction, intravenous drug use spread
across Asia from Pakistan to Thailand, leading to a sudden surge in HIV infection through
injection. By early 1994, Burma's estimated 400,000 heroin users had the highest HIV rate
of any addict population. Between January and June 1988, the seropositive rate for sample
addict populations in Thailand had jumped from 1 to 40 percent, the edge of an epidemic
that is leading to an HIV rate now approaching a fifth of the country's population.
Increased poppy production in the Golden Triangle is being felt on the streets of American
cities. In the 1990s, heroin is back is a drug of choice and Southeast Asia is our main
source. Between 1984 and 1990, Southeast Asia's share of the New York City heroin market
rose from five to eighty percent. Following these trends, in early 1991 Southeast Asia's
contribution to the US heroin supply shot to forty-five percent, up from just eighteen
percent in 1987. Today, over eighty percent of all heroin seized in the United States
comes from the Golden Triangle.
In the early 1990s, as heroin surged into New York in unprecedented quantities, the City's
wholesale price per kilo dropped from $100,000 to $60,000--creating a new clientele for
this purer, smokeable drug. Ten years ago the purity of street heroin averaged about four
percent, but today it has jumped to sixty-five percent. In the first half of 1993,
heroin-related hospital emergencies soared to 30,800 nationwide, up forty-four percent
over 1992.
With high purity allowing smoking or snorting, heroin no long carries the risk of AIDS
infection through shared needles, shattering a barrier that had long restrained its
rediscovery. Stigmatized during the 1960s as a ghetto drug, the mark of the social
marginal, heroin has been reborn in the 1990s as the badge of the hip American nihilist.
For those at the cutting edge of a young, creative crowd known as "Generation
X," heroin is the drug of choice, the symbol of authentic alienation. On the East
Coast heroin is back as an old friend, a simple respite from the roller-coaster rip of
crack-cocaine and all its craziness. It is on the West Coast that heroin's rebirth as a
style statement has been most complete. In Los Angeles, films such as "Drug Store
Cowboy" and "My Private Idaho" have mythologized the drug, adding an allure
to addiction for the city's edge actors. In San Francisco, bands like "Pale
Horse" and "Morphine" celebrate the drug, making its trademark dragon
iconography a fashionable logo for club-cruising gear, stylish caps and t-shirts.
Seattle's "grunge movement" is wrapping the drug in an ambiguous embrace, and
the heroin-related deaths of local rock icons Andrew Love and Kurt Cobain give it a
cultish degeneracy.
Although the surge in global heroin supply in the late 1980s had complex causes, it can be
traced, in part, to two key factors--the failure in US interdiction efforts and a larger
complex of changes springing from the end of the Cold War. Specifically, the increasing
opium harvests in Burma and Afghanistan, America's major suppliers, were, in part, the
legacy of Cold War operations past and present. Just as US support for Nationalist Chinese
(KMT) troops in the Shan States increased Burma's opium crop in the 1950s, so Western
covert aid to the mujaheddin guerrillas expanded opium output in Afghanistan and linked
Pakistan's nearby heroin laboratories to the world market. After serving as the sites of
major Cold War operations that intensified indigenous ethnic insurgencies, Burma and
Afghanistan ranked, in 1993 estimates, as the world's first and second largest suppliers
of illicit heroin.
After Soviet support for the Kabul regime and US arms shipments to the rebels ended in
January 1992, Afghanistan's role as a major heroin supplier increased sharply. Indeed, in
late 1991 the United Nations anti-drug commission had reported that the Afghan guerrillas,
anticipating a cut in US covert support, were already planting a greatly expanded opium
crop as an alternative source of finance.
There is, moreover, a strong economic and ecological logic drawing Afghanistan into a
sudden and sustained increase in opium cultivation. In 1992-93, the four to six million
Afghan refugees who have lived for a decade in camps along Pakistan's Northwest Frontier
began returning to war ravaged farms with less than a thousand dollars in UN resettlement
funds. Since much of Afghanistan's agriculture involves perennial crops that take several
years to regenerate after damage or neglect, Afghan farmers have an obvious need for a
profitable annual crop. Even without the disruption of war, opium has long been the
country's most viable crop. In 1972, a US cabinet committee reported that Afghan farmers
made $300-$360 per hectare from opium, twice the average of $175 for fruit: "There is
no substitute crop--except for hashish--that can...provide anywhere near an equal
income." With the recent eruption of civil war in Kabul, Afghanistan does not have
government to negotiate either foreign aid or trade agreements for the export of primary
products, so its farmers have fallen back on an established illicit commodity with ready
markets and an informal laissez-passer at every customs barrier. Since opium cultivation
is already well established, heroin processing is skilled, and syndicate connections with
Europe are in place, the poppy is becoming is fast becoming a major economic support for
rural Afghanistan in this epoch of economic crisis.
A recent UN report published in Pakistan claimed that Afghanistan's 1991 opium crop was
already 2,000 tons, while privately UN anti-drug officials predicted a vast Afghan crop of
some 4,000 tons for 1992--a harvest large enough to double the world's entire illicit
opium supply. Although unseasonable rainfall during harvest destroyed much of that crop,
the UN's field agents still estimate, often privately, that within the next two to three
years Afghanistan has the potential to produce bumper crops of 3,000 to 4,000 tons of raw
opium. If these estimates are correct, the Afghan crop will soon exceed Southeast Asia's,
and nearly double the supply of heroin for the world market. Indeed, in the US State
Department's conservative estimates, Afghanistan's opium production increased from 415
tons in 1990 to either 685 or 900 tons by 1993.
As in Burma twenty years before, Afghanistan experienced a mix superpower confrontation
and local ethnic conflict that facilitated formation of drug networks that can continue to
grow long after Cold War intervention had ceased.
Moreover, by attacking heroin trafficking in separate sectors of Asia's extended opium
zone in isolation, the DEA inadvertently influenced the market in ways that diverted
heroin exports from America to Europe, and also shifted opium production from the South
West Asia to Southeast Asia and back again--raising both global consumption and production
with each move. Compounding this problem, White House fixation with Latin America's
cocaine traffic diverted resources from the interdiction of Asian heroin. By using a
massive interdiction effort to cut supplies of Latin American cocaine without reducing the
overall U.S. demand for drugs, the White House created a void in the cocaine/crack market
that was soon filled by increased supplies of Southeast Asia heroin. Rising without any
threat of disruption by law enforcement, the Asian heroin trade expanded during the 1980s
to provide ample supplies of an alternative narcotic when cocaine sales finally declined.
Similarly, in Latin America itself, Colombia's Cali cartel recognized the new market
opportunity and in 1991 introduced opium into the northern slopes of the Andes. Within a
year Colombia was harvesting 20 tons of opium, half of Mexico's output of 40 tons. Since
the United States only consumes about 6 tons of heroin per annum, or 60 tons of opium,
Mexico and Colombia combined could supply the entire US heroin market.
In the mid 1990s, the global narcotics trade, operating with the dynamics of a resilient
commerce, seems highly resistant to any renewed war on drugs, no matter how extreme the
strategy. Since ongoing US and UN policies seem incapable of restraining the opium trade,
there is reason to be pessimistic about trends in the global drug problem over the medium
term. Although any prediction about a complex social phenomenon like drugs is prone to
error, there are indications that we are at the threshold of a major change in the world
drug market. In its recent spread across Central Asia, the opium poppy may have found a
natural home where economy, ecology, and society may encourage an quantum increase in
production during the next decade. Just as Szechwan Province once produced 10,000 tons of
opium, so Afghanistan, Tajikistan, and Uzbekistan are capable, individually or severally,
of comparable harvests. Assuming that production in Southeast Asia continues, there is no
reason that world opium supply cannot double from the present 4,000 tons in five years and
double again in another five.
Looking into the future of the opium trade, there seem four apparent trends: (1.) a rapid,
even dramatic, growth in world opium supply during the coming decade; (2.) a parallel
increase in global consumption of opiates, with increased abuse in established areas and
an extension of use to new countries or continents; (3.) spread of communicable diseases,
such as AIDS and Hepatitis-B, through intravenous injection of heroin; and, (4.) rise in
the negative social side-effects of mass heroin use--in particular, police corruption,
political venality, syndicate violence, organized crime penetration of politics,
gender-specific petty criminality, ethnic insurgency, and illegal arms trading.
b.) Statistics from Sources & Text for "Politics of Heroin":
1.) Increase/decrease in World Opium Production:
--During this five-year period, world opium production dropped slightly from 4,105 tons in 1989 to 3,969 tons in 1993.
2.) Changes in Opium Cultivation by Region:
--In Southeast Asia's Golden Triangle opium production dropped slightly from 2,956 tons in 1989 to 2,797 tons in 1993.
--Burma's opium production remained constant, changing from 2,528 tons in 1989 to 2,575 in 1993.
--In Southwest Asia (Iran, Afghanistan, Pakistan, Lebanon) production was constant, changing from 1,060 in 1989 to 1,099 in 1993.
--In Afghanistan opium production rose from 585 tons in 1989 to more than 900 tons in 1993.
--Starting opium cultivation, Colombia's production remained largely unchanging, dropping slightly from 27 tons in 1991 to 20 tons in 1993.
3.) Changes in Quantity of Opium Consumption by Region:
--In the United States, the heroin addict population rose from 450,000 in 1982 to some 750,000 in 1993.
--Rising from low levels in the late 1970s, Burma's estimated addict population reached an estimated 400,000 in early 1994.
--In Thailand, the estimated population of heroin addicts rose from 125,000 in 1986 to 375,000 in 1993.
c.) Summary and Analysis of Trends within Epoch:
1.) Globalization: In the early 1990s, world opium supply is growing without any apparent restraint. Since all opium produced is always consumed, rising supply is now a powerful force driving a sharp increase in world heroin consumption, creating powerful demands that may, in turn, yield further production increases in Latin America or Central Asia. In the 1990s, we are perhaps witnessing a recurrence of the pattern first evidenced in late 18th Century China: once mass opiate addiction is introduced to a market, demand becomes nearly insatiable and serves to stimulate further increases in global supply.
2.) Opium Production & Consumption: In the past decade, both production and consumption of opiates have increased in established zones and spread quickly into new areas.
3.) Prognosis: If current trends continue, there is no reason that world opium production, and consumption, should not double every five years into the foreseeable future.
III. PRODUCTION PATTERNS & POLICY IMPLICATIONS:
1.) Observations on Changing Patterns:
a.) Consumption Axiom: Over the past 300 years, all opium produced has been consumed. Accurate estimates of production will therefore yield the most accurate estimates of gross consumption.
b.) Bilateral Suppression: As demonstrated in Turkey in the 1970s and the Andes in the 1980s, bilateral suppression efforts can effect dramatic short-term reductions in supply but will, in the next crop year, lead to an increase in total global production of narcotics.
c.) Consumption: As shown by DEA operations in Thailand in the mid 1970s, bilateral heroin interdiction efforts can succeed in substantially reducing drug shipments to a single consuming nation. However, heroin supplies, when denied entry into one market, seek another, resulting a global proliferation of consumption and overall increase in world demand for opiates.
d.) Synthetic Substitutes: Through a succession of successful bilateral interdiction and suppression operations in Turkey, Thailand, and Mexico throughout the 1970s, the United States succeeded in temporarily reducing its domestic availability of heroin. However, criminal syndicates in the United States reacted to the shortage of natural drugs by rapidly expanding domestic manufacture of synthetics, producing the "speed" or amphetamine epidemic of the late 1970s.
e.) China's Perfect Coercion: Judging by the dramatic success of opium eradication
efforts in the People's Republic of China during the 1950s, we can conclude that perfect
repression under an efficient authoritarian regime can effect a dramatic reduction in both
consumption and production of drugs. Judging, moreover, from the recent spread of heroin
use and smuggling in southwest China during the last five years, even China's modest
reduction in authoritarian controls through its development of capitalism can lead to a
parallel resurgence in a country's drug problem. To summarize: perfect coercion can
suppress drug use but imperfect coercion cannot.
In sum, China's experience is historically unique and is not relevant as a model for
current drug control in capitalist democracies. The authoritarian states of right and left
that rose during the Cold War are fast yielding to more open political and economic
systems akin to free-market democracy. In opening themselves to market economics, these
nations, like China itself, are reducing their repressive capacities and opening
themselves to criminality of all sorts, drug trafficking included. In this post-Cold War
world, a lesson from what may have the most authoritarian state in a era of global
repression has limited relevance.
f.) State Power: In circumstances where either opium production or consumption are
legal, an efficient state can effect a rapid change in drug supply and use. During the
period 1906 to 1934, multilateral efforts by the League of Nations succeeded in reducing
global opium production from 41,600 tons to 16,600. These measures were successful, in
large part, because they were multinational and because the states involved were
regulating a legal production and consumption that was, in effect, under their control.
Similarly, in the 1970s, the Turkish government affected a total eradication of opium
production within two years because all its poppy farmers were licensed by the state's
Turkish Marketing Organization as producers for legitimate pharmaceutical companies.
Approaching the question of the state from another perspective, the lessons of the past
century indicate that opium production cannot continue over the long term in a strong
state committed to its eradication. Conversely, protracted, high-level opium production
requires either the attenuation of state power in the producing regions, as in Burma and
Afghanistan in the 1980s, or extensive official corruption, as Thailand in the 1960s, Laos
in the 1970s, or Burma in the 1990s. Thus, any cluster of policies that increases state
control over opium producing regions and simultaneously restrains official corruption over
drugs will contribute to a long-term reduction in both cultivation and trafficking.
g.) Response to Repression: Market response to all government control and eradication efforts is complex and unpredictable. Most importantly, since the 1920s criminal syndicates have emerged as a market response to League of Nations suppression efforts and have now become an important, independent economic force, mediating between the illicit demand for drugs and government suppression programs. Syndicate response to all state suppression efforts is quick, supple, and sophisticated, and is often capable of compromising even the best attempts.
h.) Unpredictable Market Reaction: Even the most effective multilateral opium suppression efforts have complex, unpredictable negative consequences. For example, the UN Drug Control Program in Thailand succeeded in reducing the opium cultivation, thereby raising the price of smoking opium to local addicts. Since opium smoking now costs some 80 baht per day versus only 10 baht for heroin, Thai addicts shifted to intravenous injection, producing an epidemic of HIV infection through needle sharing.
i.) Consequences of Man-Land Ratios: Projecting long-term demographic and ecological changes forward over the next half-century leads to some contradictory and inconclusive trends:
a.) As has already occurred in the Thai highlands, population pressures will reduce the open hill landscape and thus may tend to bring lowland government services and controls into the opium-growing zones. More people per square kilometer would create the fiscal base and political imperative for government to extend services such as roads and communications, bringing in their train improved para-military access and increased state controls.
b.) Over the medium term, such population pressures could drive highland population towards increased opium cultivation since the poppy is a cash crop with a higher income per hectare than subsistence or market-garden crops.
j.) Political Trends in Post Cold-War Era: With remarkable speed and facility,
multi-national corporations and telecommunications are pulling us towards a global
community. The spread of such communications might promote a subtle sense of shared
humanity that will perhaps erode the cultural disdain that has allowed states, such as
British India, to inflict mass drug addiction upon a people deemed "inferior" or
simply "other." Simultaneously, however, there is an equally powerful
countervailing trend toward the assertion of primordial identities that may well have the
opposite effect, at least over the short term.
For forty years, the Cold War imposed an arbitrary, artificial bipolar division over the
globe that led rival superpowers to the defend the territorial integrity of their
respective client states. With the end of the Cold War, there has then been a
recrudescence of the primordial, essential elements of politics obscured by the past
half-century of global conflict--that is, religion, regionalism, race, and ethnicity.
Given shape and force by armed revolts, these primal identities may well lead to the
fragmentation of the invented nations that were carved out of the colonial world at the
end of World War II. The rise of new micro-states from the margins of established nations
has several possible implications for future opium production.
a.) During a period of insurgency against an established state, rebel groups, like Khun Sa's Mong Tai Army, will become more dependent upon opium finance and will thus resist any attempt by the central government, their enemy, to introduce any form of control, including drug repression or crop substitution. As the insurgency grows, the established nation-state will be increasingly unable to impose such programs.
b.) Faced with the threat of regional secessionist movements, nation states will become less able or willing to impose disruptive, unpopular opium-control programs upon volatile minority areas.
c.) Once an ethnic group secedes to form a new nation, the newly established mini-states will, in all probability, become more cooperative with UN and US drug control programs to win a full package of international aid, avoid the internal destabilization of the drug trade, and consolidate the new state's controls over its periphery.
2.) Policy Implications of Historic Patterns:
a.) Multilateral Policy: During the 20th Century, the historical record indicates that
multilateral efforts have been more effective than bilateral initiatives in effecting
narcotics suppression. From 1906 to 1934, multilateral efforts by the League of Nations
reduced global opium production from 41,624 tons to an estimated 16,653. By contrast,
between 1970 and 1990, an era of the intense US bilateral "drug wars," world
illicit opium production increased from 1,154 tons to 4,209.
Although these figures conceal as much as they reveal, they do nonetheless indicate the
greater potential for success in multilateral operations. Since bilateral operations are,
by their very nature, focused on a single producing country, market dynamics will mean
that, over the long term, a successful eradication will stimulate illicit price and
production elsewhere, leading to a net global increase in opium supply.
b.) Supply Reduction--Opium Eradication: Any attempt at solving America's heroin
problem by reducing global opium production is utterly unrealistic. For the past two
decades, three administrations--under presidents Nixon, Reagan, and Bush--have waged a
"war on drugs" with the aim of ameliorating America's narcotics problem by
reducing global drug supply.
If we subject this policy to close examination it seems, from the vantage point of
historical hindsight, absurd. In 1985, for example, the United States consumed only 6 tons
of opium out of a world production of 1,465 tons--just 0.4 percent of the total. Since the
United States offers the widest profit margin for dealers at all levels beyond the
farmgate, it will, through the logic of market forces, consume the world's
"last" 6 tons of opium. In effect, the drug war strategy requires that the
United States eradicate 99 percent of the world's opium before it gets to that last,
critical 1 percent destined for the American market.
While UN multilateral efforts may well eradicate world opium supply within a half century
or so, the elimination of 99 percent of the world's opium production seems far beyond the
capacities of US bilateral efforts at current or foreseeable funding levels. Complicating
the issue further, opium cultivation is spreading rapidly to new areas in Central Asia and
Latin America, raising total world supply and greatly complicating the task of
eradication. Given declining US resources and rising world opium production, a supply-side
solution to the US heroin problem must be deemed an impossibility.
c.) Demand Reduction: Looking back on the past 300 years of human history, there are only a very few societies that have succeeded in reducing their level of gross opiates consumption:
1.) US (1914-45): Between World War I and World War II, the United States managed to reduce its overall level of opiates consumption through a series of demand-side measures. By banning legal narcotics sales between 1914 and 1923, the US gained the instruments to suppress legal use, effecting a gradual gross reduction in use. Simultaneously, a mass campaign of education and moral injunction educated the American people to avoid opiates addiction, a phenomenon that was only gradually being analyzed and understood. Finally, a brief but dramatic drop in supply during World War II produced a short but marked reduction in US heroin consumption.
2.) China (1949-59): During the decade following its revolution, the People's Republic of China used a mix of coercion, compulsory treatment, and mass education to eliminate the world's largest opiate addict population.
3.) United States (1975-80): During the late 1970s, the transitory effect of successful drug suppression in Turkey and Thailand combined with a drop in demand as Vietnam-era addicts weaned themselves from the drug combined to produce a sudden drop in the estimated number of American addicts from 500,000 to 200,000. Since the demand change was specific to the experience of a single generation and the supply reduction was ephemeral, the fundamental demand for heroin remained and abuse levels rose again in the 1980s as supplies increased.
d.) Education & Treatment: Since world opium production has been rising, and
suppression efforts are not effective, the best remedies to the drug problem may lie in
domestic demand reduction through treatment, education, and societal change. Independent
social movements have long record of success in changing social attitudes towards drugs
and effecting a marked reduction in demand. In Holland during the late 19th century,
temperance movements reduced an epidemic of alcohol addiction.
Similarly, in the United States the Nation of Islam has been effective against drug use in
African-American communities. Among the white middle-class during the 1980s, MADD (Mothers
Against Drunk Driving) has produced a reduction in drunk driving fatalities and the
personal fitness movement, with its exquisite consciousness of the body, has led a major
decline in cocaine use.
e.) Drug Education: While treatment and teen-aged education about drugs have ambiguous
results, broadly framed education of pre-teens (seven to eleven years old) about body,
health, and life choices might contribute to a change in attitudes and serve to preempt
the later appeal that drugs might have.
Although those in drug enforcement seem sometimes dismissive of the potential of education
to influence the level of abuse, there are some contemporary American examples that
indicate otherwise. Recent anti-smoking campaigns--aimed at age groups below the age that
the habit is formed--have shown some success in discouraging tobacco use among the young.
Like all such campaigns, drug education will have to be integrated into the school
curriculum and be repeated year-after-year for each new generation to effect a sustained
cultural change.
f.) Policy Paradigms: Over the past half-century, US drug policy has been framed, in
succession, around two inappropriate paradigms of coercion. During the 1950s and 1960s ,
the old Federal Bureau of Narcotics applied the classic 19th century police
paradigm--extirpation of local vice by application of sufficient repression. While such a
model is appropriate for municipal law enforcement, it becomes counter-productive when
applied to a global commodity trade like heroin. Assuming direct control of drug policy
since 1973, the White House has applied the martial metaphor of war to the narcotics
problem, applying the military logic of short, intense campaigns with fixed spatial or
strategic objectives to an elusive global commodity.
Recognizing the power of paradigms to shape concepts and thereby frame policy, it might be
best to adopt a more appropriate health or disease paradigm for US drug policy. At the
level of domestic drug abuse, our policy should be removed from the criminal justice
system and returned to the realm of public health where it could be handled like a
virulent disease such as tuberculosis or influenza. Under this medical metaphor for
heroin, we might, at the international level, adopt the paradigm and procedures of the WHO
campaigns against epidemic disease. From this new perspective, past U.S. policy with its
mix of bilateral suppression and domestic repression might seem rather like dealing with a
global epidemic of smallpox or yellow fever by trying to seal the country's borders
against the microbes. Like a virulent, communicable disease, a global commodity such as
opium can be eradicated only through a cooperative world-wide effort.
g.) Customs Barrier: Although strict controls at the national frontier are limited in their effectiveness, they do nonetheless serve as an informal customs barrier that can at least restrain the entry of drugs. Just as high protective tariffs discourage but do not eliminate legal imports, so an efficient customs operation can serve as informal market factor that discourages, within limits, unrestricted narcotics imports. Similarly, dropping the custom shield might serve as informal invitation to illicit drug imports.
h.) Need for Reliable Indicators of Progress: As indicated throughout this report, one
of the small but significant problems bedeviling the formation of an effective policy is
the plasticity of all drug statistics on consumption and production. Since there have been
few reliable standards of progress in reducing either production or consumption, officials
have difficulties in distinguishing between false and true indicators.
Until all government agencies, academic specialists, and media evolve a valid, universal
standard of measurement, mistakes will continue to compound the problem and debate will
continue to flail between extremes. For example, instead of emphasizing the spectacle of
large drug seizures, officials and media might focus on the less dramatic trends of
illicit price and area of cultivation. Similarly, manufacturing estimates of addiction
from guesses or crude ratios should yield to neighborhood surveys and accurate assessment
of both hospital and coroner's reports.
i.) Need for Caution in Framing Any Policy: In any discussion of solutions to the problem of global opium supply, we must begin with an essential humility. Any drug that finds such resonance within the chemistry of the human brain, any commodity that is so interwoven into the fabric of modern capitalism, cannot be easily eliminated, even with the most judicious policy. Our ignorance of the global heroin traffic is profound, and any policy we adopt will, in all likelihood, have an unforeseen consequences for the trade in this global commodity.
3.) Scenarios for Future Policy Options:
a.) Continued Repression: If the United States continues its current policy of repression--with international bilateral operations, Customs controls, and domestic policing--then the probable outcome will be over the long term might be as follows.
1.) Projecting current patterns forward, heroin use will continue grow both domestically and globally, the crime rate will climb, and the US prison population will increase without cease.
2.) Assuming that the US continues current attempts at eradication, bilateral repression, where attempted, will continue to stimulate opium cultivation, contributing to a rapidly increasing global supply of drugs.
3.) Even if the US withdraws from international suppression operations, over the medium term there is every indication that world opium supply will continue its current rate of rapid increase.
4.) US Customs will fail to slow the import of drugs into the US, allowing the increased world opium supply to enter America and stimulate a rising level of heroin consumption.
The evidecne from the past 20 years indicates that US bilateral suppression has not effected a decrease in either cocaine or heroin supply. By contrast, US operations have stimulated long-term increases in illicit production by raising the world market price. Even without this paradoxical stimulus, the three drug wars have been both too diffuse and too localized to make a major impact on the global drug market. Today, even a well-managed US bilateral operation would have little chance in reducing the fast rising world opium cultivation, now spreading beyond Southeast an Southwest Asia into Central Asia and Latin America.
b.) Legalization: If the United States were to abandon all attempts at drug suppression and legalize narcotics, the reaction in the market would likely be far more complex than advocates of this radical policy alternative have suggested. Most fundamentally, we need to admit that the complexity of the global and national drug market mocks our limited knowledge of its dynamics. Just as our past attempts at suppression have impacted on the with unforeseen, unintended consequences, so our attempt at legalization could produce the same result: that is, compounding or worsening the problem.
1.) Adult Legalization: Assuming that drug use is legalized only for adults and not for minors, then legalization, with unrestricted legal sales to adults, might increase US consumption of narcotics:
a.) Increased global supplies of heroin will raise the purity of US street supplies, making its use for snorting safe and more pleasurable. In short, better heroin will be more appealing to more consumers.
b.) Supply will increase through legal sales, allowing a uniform and convenient nationwide distribution of drugs. For the first time since the 1890s, supply restraints on consumption will be removed, allowing narcotics use to reach its natural level.
c.) With legal distribution, the price of heroin will probably drop, reducing any economic pressure on users to restrain consumption or seek treatment.
2.) Strict Clinical Controls: If we adopt a strict clinical control system to distribute legalized heroin and cocaine to adults, then, as happened in the United Kingdom in recent decades, a parallel illegal traffic might spring up beside the legal clinics, servicing those who wish to control their own consumption.
3.) Freedom of Choice: If we adopt a laissez-faire system of legal narcotic sales, then impoverished adult users may avail of the opportunity to earn survival income by diverting supplies to underage users.
a.) Since the most popular illicit hard drug is currently crack-cocaine, and most of its users are under the age of 21, there is a potential illicit market for crack sales to minors that could be quite substantial. In effect, the proposed legalization is very partial indeed and will retain drug prohibition for the largest single segment of the current narcotics market--underage crack users.
b.) Under such circumstances, the partial legalization could create economic pressures for an expansion of narcotic abuse among minors. No longer needing a Bangkok or Cali connection, any adult can become a dealer, diverting supplies from legal outlets to underage users. Moreover, minors might be able purchase fake adult identification cards, allowing them access to legal drugs for both personal use and sale to peers. In effect, this future illicit drug market would have a logistic similar to that now operating for underage drinkers.
c.) Assuming that global supplies of illegal narcotics continue at present levels, any shortfalls in legal supplies to adults or minors in the US domestic market will, in all probability, be met by a parallel illicit system of supply.
d.) Since legal drug distribution, underage illicit use, residual narcotics trafficking, and related criminal violence will be concentrated in Hispanic and African-American communities, legalization might lead to an escalation in racial tensions. Community leaders might raise protests that minorities are being subjected a form of drug policy "red lining."
e.) Under these circumstances, legalization, or more accurately, a "partial legalization," might create some combination of high-volume distribution for legal heroin, diversion of legal supplies to minors, and survival of an illicit market--leading ultimately to a dramatic increase in total US heroin consumption.
c.) Policy of "Regulation:" Instead of the drug war with its doomed attempt at a total eradication of drug use, there are several policy alternatives the US could adopt to improve the narcotics situation. Between the poles of unrestrained repression and the much publicized idea of "legalization," we might attempt a new policy called "regulation"--carefully gauging each element for its impact on this complex commodity trade. If America's drug problem cannot be solved, then at least it can be managed rationally. Among its elements would be some of the following.
1.) DEA: By forcing the DEA to abandon its unreflective buy-and-bust approach, the US government can restrain the DEA from inadvertently stimulating global opium production with its bilateral interdiction.
2.) Multilateral Effort: After abandoning the DEA's bilateral enforcement effort, we can shift a portion of our international interdiction funds to the UN's long-term, multilateral crop substitution efforts. If we are correct when we speak in medical metaphor of a "heroin epidemic," then the solution to this world health problem will have to be multilateral and global. Just as unilateral or bilateral public health efforts are useless against communicable diseases, so the same might be true in the eradication of global opium production. Over the long-term, simultaneous, coordinated efforts at opium control might actually reduce world supply instead of stimulating it as bilateral operations have.
3.) Demand Reduction: Given the complexity of the global drug trade, there is no bilateral, short-term, supply-side solution to the US drug problem. Consequently, we must divert much current drug war budget from repression to education and treatment.
4.) Custom's Barrier: Since all drugs imported into the United States are consumed, we should maintain an effective Customs barrier to minimize the smuggling of illicit narcotics. Under this policy of regulation, we might be advised to abandon our quest for the chimera of "eradication" and instead determine the optimum level of narcotics this country can tolerate. Sudden shortages, through effective seizures, are disruptive and destructive in the illicit market. Moreover, a complete eradication of natural narcotics, cocaine and heroin, might encourage production of new, lethal synthetics with negative consequences for the quality of life in urban America.
5.) Decriminalization: As a part of this putative strategy of "regulation," we might seriously consider "decriminalization" of narcotics possession of small quantities for personal use or petty sales. Instead of mandatory prison terms for possession of small amounts of drugs, reformed laws might mandate compulsory treatment, relieving the mounting pressure on our prisons and the public purse that supports them. After remaining more or less constant at 100 prisoners per 100,000 population for a half century, the US prison rate, driven by mandatory drug sentencing, shot up from 138 in 1980 to 455 in 1990--by far the highest for any nation. Cutting the high costs of incarceration and new prison construction would free significant resources for education, job training, and treatment. To summarize, decriminalization will have some of the following advantages:
a.) Allow substantial reduction in the nation's prison population.
b.) Allow a diversion of social resources from prison maintenance and construction to alternative social programs--job training, drug treatment, drug education, and community development.
c.) Reducing convictions for drug possession and petty sales will decrease the percentage of young African-American males processed through the criminal justice system, lowering both government costs and social tensions.
6.) Needle Exchange: Under the critical review of existing drug laws that will accompany this policy of regulation, the benefits of banning the free purchase of hypodermic syringes should be examined. Although the policy has been in place for decades, there is little evidence that these restrictions have in any way reduced the level of drug addiction. Other nations, such as Australia, have pursed a policy of vigorous enforcement while allowing free purchase of syringes. As our national AIDS epidemic moves into its second decade, it has become clear the ban on syringe sales has led to a rising seropositive rate among intravenous drug users. Perhaps it is time to ask: is the cost in rising HIV infection really worth the gain in terms reducing drug abuse?
7.) Regulated Supply: Rather than letting drug sales rise to their natural level through legalization or seeking a sudden reduction in supply by short-term repression, the logic of this policy aims for a gradual diminution in narcotics and hard drug consumption over long-term. To avoid repeating the experience of the late 1970s when a sudden heroin shortage stimulated domestic production of synthetic drugs, the US and UN policy should be coordinated to affect a slow, steady decline in world opiates supply. In effect, the United States should avoid the para-military operations that blitz a particular production or smuggling zone to produce dramatic, albeit ephemeral, disruptions in domestic supply.
8.) No Solution: Ultimately we must realize that there is no "quick fix" to
the US drug problem. Through this policy of regulation we can stop the American state from
using its considerable power to compound the problem. Then we can slow and stabilize the
level of domestic drug use, working over the long-term for a gradual amelioration.
IV. NOTES FOR TEXT & TABLES: